Skip to main content
Advertisement
Browse Subject Areas
?

Click through the PLOS taxonomy to find articles in your field.

For more information about PLOS Subject Areas, click here.

  • Loading metrics

Projecting Global Land-Use Change and Its Effect on Ecosystem Service Provision and Biodiversity with Simple Models

  • Erik Nelson ,

    enelson2@bowdoin.edu

    Affiliation The Natural Capital Project, Woods Institute for the Environment, Stanford University, Stanford, California, United States of America

  • Heather Sander,

    Current address: National Exposure Research Laboratory, Ecological Exposure Research Division, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Cincinnati, Ohio, United States of America

    Affiliation Conservation Biology Graduate Program, University of Minnesota, St. Paul, Minnesota, United States of America

  • Peter Hawthorne,

    Affiliation Department of Ecology, Evolution, and Behavior, University of Minnesota, St. Paul, Minnesota, United States of America

  • Marc Conte,

    Affiliation The Natural Capital Project, Woods Institute for the Environment, Stanford University, Stanford, California, United States of America

  • Driss Ennaanay,

    Affiliation The Natural Capital Project, Woods Institute for the Environment, Stanford University, Stanford, California, United States of America

  • Stacie Wolny,

    Affiliation The Natural Capital Project, Woods Institute for the Environment, Stanford University, Stanford, California, United States of America

  • Steven Manson,

    Affiliation Department of Geography, University of Minnesota, Minneapolis, Minnesota, United States of America

  • Stephen Polasky

    Affiliations Conservation Biology Graduate Program, University of Minnesota, St. Paul, Minnesota, United States of America, Department of Applied Economics, University of Minnesota, St. Paul, Minnesota, United States of America

Abstract

Background

As the global human population grows and its consumption patterns change, additional land will be needed for living space and agricultural production. A critical question facing global society is how to meet growing human demands for living space, food, fuel, and other materials while sustaining ecosystem services and biodiversity [1].

Methodology/Principal Findings

We spatially allocate two scenarios of 2000 to 2015 global areal change in urban land and cropland at the grid cell-level and measure the impact of this change on the provision of ecosystem services and biodiversity. The models and techniques used to spatially allocate land-use/land-cover (LULC) change and evaluate its impact on ecosystems are relatively simple and transparent [2]. The difference in the magnitude and pattern of cropland expansion across the two scenarios engenders different tradeoffs among crop production, provision of species habitat, and other important ecosystem services such as biomass carbon storage. For example, in one scenario, 5.2 grams of carbon stored in biomass is released for every additional calorie of crop produced across the globe; under the other scenario this tradeoff rate is 13.7. By comparing scenarios and their impacts we can begin to identify the global pattern of cropland and irrigation development that is significant enough to meet future food needs but has less of an impact on ecosystem service and habitat provision.

Conclusions/Significance

Urban area and croplands will expand in the future to meet human needs for living space, livelihoods, and food. In order to jointly provide desired levels of urban land, food production, and ecosystem service and species habitat provision the global society will have to become much more strategic in its allocation of intensively managed land uses. Here we illustrate a method for quickly and transparently evaluating the performance of potential global futures.

Introduction

The earth's capacity to provide enough living space, food, and clean water to meet human needs as well as the habitat needs of other species is being severely tested [3][5]. A growing global human population and the associated increase in demand for living space, food, water, fuel, and other materials and services makes ecosystem service and biodiversity sustenance a difficult challenge. Having a clear understanding of how ecosystem service and habitat provision might change over time due to global urban and cropland development is a prerequisite for charting a global future that can meet these interconnected challenges [1]. In this paper, we develop methods for allocating expected areal changes in global land use/land cover (LULC) and for analyzing the likely consequences of these changes on the provision of several ecosystem services and species habitat.

Our approach provides a relatively simple and transparent method for creating spatially-explicit projections of global LULC change at the grid cell-level. Our spatial allocation of expected urban and cropland areal development is guided by rules that incorporate basic demographic, economic development, and biophysical principles. This method allows for the relatively quick creation of spatially-explicit projections of business-as-usual futures or alternative futures that might emerge if decision-making on urban and cropland development across the world changes, either due to shifts in consumption preferences or land-use policies.

We couple global LULC conversion scenarios with models that predict the consequences of these changes on the provision of crop, water availability, carbon storage in biomass (a climate regulation service), and habitat for species. Changes in ecosystem service provision are modeled using the Integrated Valuation of Ecosystem Services and Tradeoffs (InVEST) software system. InVEST is a suite of geographic information science models and algorithms that converts changes in LULC patterns into changes in terrestrial carbon storage, water availability, crop production, habitat for species, and other ecosystem service outputs (not all services modeled by InVEST are included in this illustration). Combining maps of alternative LULC futures with InVEST, we can estimate the range of potential changes in ecosystem service provision and tradeoffs among various services at different geographical and socioeconomic scales. These predictions can help frame the discussion of preferred global change outcomes and policy mechanisms needed to obtain them.

To illustrate our approach, we create two plausible scenarios of spatially-explicit LULC change for the period 2000 to 2015. To create a scenario we estimate global areal change in urban land and cropland from 2000 to 2015 and then spatially allocate the change at the grid cell-level. Cropland areal growth across the globe under the country scenario is given by extrapolating country-level 1985 to 2000 cropland growth trends to the 2000 to 2015 period [6]. Cropland areal growth across the globe under the regional scenario is based on estimates of regional growth in cropland area as given by the OECD-FAO's Agricultural Outlook trade model [7] where a region can be comprised of one country (e.g., the U.S.) or many countries (e.g., sub-Saharan Africa). Both scenarios assume the same level and pattern of urbanization [8]. Therefore, differences across the two scenarios are completely explained by divergent cropland development patterns. In this illustration, the area of grid cells classified as urban increases 23.6% across the globe between 2000 and 2015, a gain of 0.76 million sq. km2. The area of grid cells classified as cropland increases by 1.48 million sq. km2 (a 5.8% increase compared to 2000) under the country scenario and by 1.88 million sq. km2 (a 7.4% increase compared to 2000) under the regional scenario. The country scenario is distinguished by significant cropland expansion in China and Indonesia while the regional scenario is highlighted by significant cropland expansion in Brazil with net cropland abandonment in China.

We translate LULC changes under each scenario into changes in crop production, water availability, carbon storage in biomass, and species habitat using InVEST. The expansion of urban and cropland area leads to global declines in species habitat and biomass carbon storage. However, as measured by impact on global ecosystem services and habitat loss, the country scenario is superior to the regional scenario. First, the country scenario generates a greater increase in the caloric value of crop production. Second, under the country scenario the gain in caloric production is done more efficiently as measured by the tradeoffs between biomass carbon storage and species habitat provision. Specifically, under the country scenario 5.2 grams of biomass carbon is released due to LULC conversion for every additional calorie of crop produced. Under the regional scenario this tradeoff rate is 13.7. Further, under the country scenario 0.0016 square meters of species habitat is lost for every additional calorie of crop produced. Under the regional scenario this tradeoff rate is 0.0021.

The superiority of the country scenario is due primarily to two global development patterns. First, under the country scenario, large sources of biomass carbon storage are not converted to cropland when compared to the regional scenario. For example, significant cropland development in Brazil under the regional scenario, an important source of global biomass carbon stock, largely explains that scenario's relatively poor performance on the crop – carbon emissions tradeoff ratio. Second, under the country scenario there is greater cropland expansion in areas with greater agricultural technological and irrigation capacities, both important factors in sustaining continued increases in crop production efficiencies. For example, under the country scenario 62.3% of the net gain in cropland grid cell area is projected to be irrigated to some degree whereas under the regional scenario only 33.1% of net gain in cropland grid cell area is projected to be irrigated to some degree. These results highlight the general principle that the likelihood of meeting the joint challenge of sufficiently increasing food production while maintaining ecosystem service and species habitat provision will increase if we allocate cropland to areas of high or increasing agricultural productivity that do not also provide high levels of ecosystem services or important habitat. Developed countries currently have the highest agricultural productivity capacities and contain some of the least important sources of several ecosystem services and species habitat due to past development [9]. Therefore, if higher agricultural productivity capacities cannot effectively be transferred to the developing world then best hope for a sustainable future may be a reverse in the recent trend of minimal to no cropland growth in the developed world [6], [7].

Besides describing potential futures and their ramifications on ecosystem service and habitat provision, projections of LULC change can be used to inform policy [10]. We illustrate how our approach can be used to guide a policy that provides incentives to maintain carbon stocks in forest at risk for development (reducing carbon emissions from deforestation and forest degradation or REDD program [11]). Assuming that the scenarios described here are two examples of business-as-usual global development projections and using a plausible REDD policy framework, we estimate 0.1 billion metric tons of avoided carbon emission credits would have been generated across the globe from 2000 to 2015 under modest offset prices if the country scenario had been chosen as the baseline and 13 billion metric tons of avoided carbon emission credits would have been generated across the globe if the regional scenario formed the baseline. The stark differences in credit creation across the two scenarios illustrates how contentious the selection of a business-as-usual emission trajectory for any actual deforestation avoidance program may be [12], [13].

Literature review: modeling global or regional LULC change at the grid cell-level

Spatially-explicit regional and global LULC change modeling has been the focus of several prominent research efforts. For example, the Millennium Ecosystem Assessment (MA) research team has developed four plausible projections of the earth's future. Each projection or scenario is defined by regional population, economic, and technological growth estimates as well as projections for food and energy demands to the year 2100 [14][16]. Using a set of climate, agricultural [17], water supply and use [18], [19], and LULC change models [20], [21], the MA team translated these expected regional change and demand trajectories into global grid cell-level LULC maps for the years 2050 and 2100 [22].

Instead of modeling change with such general equilibrium models, extent and pattern of LULC change can be generated by simulating the decision making of actors on the landscape. In agent-based modeling “agents” (e.g., households, firms, government agencies, etc.) make LULC decisions over time such that their preferences are maximized given land-use policy constraints and their neighbors' decisions [23], [24]. Alternatively, instead of simulating the behavior of agents through time, previous LULC change behavior on the landscape can be extrapolated into the future using one of several statistical techniques [25], [26], including cellular automata [27][29]. In agent-based modeling the challenge is getting the rules that guide agent behavior correct. The challenge with the statistical approach is 1) isolating and controlling for policy, biophysical, or economic conditions that shaped past decisions but will not exist in the future and 2) appropriately controlling for conditions that could affect future LULC decision making but were not present on the landscape in the past [30].

In other global and regional change research, the spatial allocation of LULC change is guided by a set of rules based on fundamental socioeconomic and biophysical principles. For example, McDonald et al. spatially allocate a United Nation's projection of country-level urban population growth across a grid using the notion that cities grow concentrically [31]. The California Urban Futures Model [32] allocates expected regional residential development such that undeveloped parcels modeled to have the highest profitability in residential land use are converted first. Alternatively, focus groups of appropriate experts and decision-makers have been used to codify the socio-economic, policy, and biophysical forces that drive LULC change across a region [33][35]. The model UPlan opens such rule-making ability to anyone [36]. In this GIS model users specify future population levels, demographic characteristics, and land-use density parameters. Given these inputs, area needed for each land-use is determined and then is spatially allocated according to user-defined or default land-use suitability maps. All of these approaches that use rules to spatially allocate LULC change tend to be simpler and more transparent than the general equilibrium scenario analysis as exemplified by the MA, agent-based modeling, or statistical analyses. However, these approaches do not verify that the resulting spatial patterns of LULC change are compatible with projected global or regional demands for food, energy, and other services or that the projected spatial patterns of change are consistent with past behavior.

Literature review: estimating the impact of grid cell-level LULC change at global scales on environment, ecosystem services, and human well-being

Many analyses that estimate the environmental or human welfare impact of expected global LULC change work with maps where change is summarized at the country- or regional-level. Such analyses have been used to predict changes in global agriculture production, disease risk, energy use, species persistence, and water availability [3], [37][40]. However, such broad assessments ignore the heterogeneity in land uses and biophysical and economic conditions within regions.

To correct for such biases researchers are increasingly using grid cell-level assessments of global LULC change to project changes in the environment, ecosystem services, and human well-being. Such an approach is capable of capturing local-scale heterogeneity that is often important for determining the supply, demand, and value of ecosystem services. The MA project is a prominent example of this. The MA used already-published economic, biophysical, and ecosystem service models [41] to estimate the impact of their four 2100 grid cell-level LULC maps on the environment, ecosystem service production, biodiversity, and human well-being [22], [42]. The LULC change model used by the MA has been used in conjunction with other biophysical and climate models to generate global maps of predicted net primary productivity and climate modulation [43], land-use carbon emissions and other carbon cycle dynamics [44][47], trends in biodiversity [48], [49], food production [50][52], inorganic nitrogen export to coastal waters [53], and of various environmental conditions [54]. McDonald et al. estimate the impact of their future global urban area map on species persistence and protected areas in each terrestrial ecoregion on the globe [31]. Other ecosystem service models that can be used with global grid cell-level LULC maps are summarized in [55].

In this paper we spatially allocate already published country- or regional-level estimates of urban and cropland area change to the grid cell-level using a rules-based approach. The inclusion of cropland areal change and the use of land-use suitability matrices to guide LULC change extend this work beyond McDonald et al. 's work. Further, unlike, McDonald et al., we consider more than biodiversity impacts of LULC change around the globe. We produce some of the same output as the MA and other global ecosystem service analyses but without using some of the more complicated demographic, economic, and technological growth and biophysical models. In fact, the models we use from InVEST to model the impact of global change are open-source, freely available, and readily accessible (http://invest.ecoinformatics.org/).The simpler and more transparent approach lowers the barriers to participation in scenario building and ecosystem service provision modeling and allows for the quick and transparent assessment of future scenarios of change. We hope that a demonstration of our transparent and flexible method for modeling the potential ramifications of global change leads to wider use of our or similar modeling approaches by policy-makers throughout the world [56], [57].

Our method for estimating the impact of grid cell-level LULC change at global scales on environment, ecosystem services, and human well-being

We spatially allocate projected country- or regional-level 2000 to 2015 net change in urban and cropland area to the grid cell-level (5 km resolution at the equator). Country-level urbanization projections for 2015 are based on urban population expansion estimates from the United Nations [8]. We spatially allocate two different projections of cropland areal change. The first projection of change is generated by extrapolating the rate of country-level cropland area change from 1985 to 2000 to the 2000 to 2015 time period (the country scenario). In the other cropland change scenario (the regional scenario), we use the OECD-FAO's Agricultural Outlook trade model [7] to estimate 2015 cropland area targets at the regional-level. The spatial extent and pattern of cropland change varies across the two scenarios because of differences in expectations for areal change and the geographic unit of analysis. For example, in the regional scenario cropland growth is greater in developing countries than it is under the country scenario.

Spatial allocation of expected urban and cropland change is done using a cellular modeling technique [58], [59]. Under this technique, urban expansion between 2000 and 2015 tends to occur in cells that are near urban land as of 2000 and that have higher urban suitability scores. A cell's urban suitability score 1) increases in its projected 2015 population density [60] and 2) decreases in its slope [61]. Urban expansion into protected areas is not allowed [62].

Then we use the cellular modeling technique and a cropland suitability map to spatially allocate a scenario's expected country-level or regional-level net growth in cropland area (or abandonment if appropriate) to the grid cell-level. Cropland expansion only occurs on land that is arable, is not in protected areas, and has not been allocated to urban expansion (i.e., we assume that urban land expansion will outbid cropland expansion on land highly suitable for both [4]). The cropland suitability map has higher scores in grid cells where 1) cereal yield potential under intensive management, including irrigation if applicable, is higher [63] and 2) slopes are gentler [61]. Potential cereal yield tends to be higher in areas with fecund soil, that has sufficient water (either due to rainfall, irrigation, or both), and have temperate climatic conditions. In the end we generate two gridded maps of LULC as of 2015 where urban grid cell extent and pattern is the same across both maps but cropland grid cell extent and pattern differ.

Even though we believe our suitability maps have captured the basic principles that drive urban and cropland change (in the urban case, we are adopting the basic principles of change assumed by [60]), we acknowledge that our suitability maps ignore many dynamics that guide LULC change. For example, infrastructure development plays a key role in both urban and cropland conversion [64]; our suitability maps do not explicitly capture existing and potential infrastructure development, investments that could increase suitability (e.g., reclaiming land through drainage or other means), and other forces of change. In the Discussion section below we note how our cropland suitability layer could be improved to capture the various forces of change that we have not included. For now we view our methodology for allocating estimated global LULC change at the grid cell-level as a first generation model that can be improved over time.

We estimate how the projected global change in LULC extent and pattern from 2000 to 2015 will affect the global provision of crops, water availability, carbon storage in biomass, and habitat for species with the appropriate InVEST models. To calculate change in global cropland production we first need to calculate change in annual harvested hectares in each country between 2000 and 2015 (we complete this and all subsequent methodological tasks for both scenarios). This calculation is a function of fallow land practices and the intensity at which the land is cropped in a country in 2000 and 2015. Next, we convert a country's pattern of change in harvested area into a change in the country's crop production (measured in both mass and caloric terms) using the InVEST agriculture model. In addition to change in harvest area, country-level change in crop production is a function of the relative change in the potential productivity of land used in the country for crop production, expected technological and infrastructure growth in the country's agricultural sector, and the mix of crops grown in the country [7], [65]. The overall productivity of the land used for cropland in a country as of 2015 will change compared to 2000's overall productivity if cropland expansion occurs on land with different yield potentials than that of cropland as of 2000. In general, if 1) the country's spatial allocation of cropland in 2015 is located on land with greater yield potential than its 2000 allocation (which can be aided by the expansion of irrigation) and/or 2) the country is expected to benefit to from yield growth in crops that dominate its 2015 crop mix, then growth in its crop production will outpace its growth in harvested area. We summarize change in crop production by country under both scenarios.

Predictions of cropland and crop production change, both in magnitude and spatial pattern, are uncertain for many reasons and we highlight a few of them here (see the Materials and Methods section for a complete discussion on sources of uncertainty). Crop yield potential is limited by water availability. Our cropland suitability layer and the base yields (observed year 2000 yields) used in the crop production model are based on water availability trends of the late 20th century (and irrigation patterns when it comes to base yields). Climate change and LULC change may result in shifts in water yield (precipitation less evapotranspiration), thereby making the cropland suitability layer and base yield estimates imperfect predictors of 2015 patterns in cropland productivity and base yields. One way we can begin to assess how crop production may deviate from modeled expectations due to climate change and LULC-driven changes in evapotranspiration is to predict average annual water yield (average annual rainfall less annual evapotranspiration in mm km−2) on each cropland grid cell in 2015. Specifically, we model average annual water yield in 2000 and 2015 on each cropland grid cell in 2015 with use HadCM3 climate model [66] and the InVEST water yield model [67][72] (we model 2000 yield instead of using actual data to keep comparisons between 2000 and 2015 consistent). If average annual water yield on a grid cell decreases over time then the cell's expected productivity as given by late 20th century climate patterns may be too high, especially if the cell primarily contains rainfed cropland. Further, a decrease in a cell's yield reduces the runoff that can be used for irrigation by other cropland grid cells downstream. With this map of annual water yield, we can identify the portions of the world where estimated crop productivity estimates, especially rainfed productivity, may be particularly vulnerable to climate change as of 2015 and beyond.

Cereal yield potential on a grid cell is partly explained by irrigation; in general, potential yield in a cell is higher if we assume a significant portion of cropland in the cell is irrigated instead of rainfed. Therefore, in this illustration, areas more likely to be irrigated in the future are more likely to be selected for cropland expansion (recall that the suitability score of a grid cell is largely determined by its relative potential for cereal production). We assign an arable cell in a country its irrigated yield potential instead of its rainfed potential on the cropland suitability layer if it has a yield potential profile that closely matches the yield potential profile of cells with significant irrigation in the country as of 2000 [73]. This modeling process creates a yield potential map where most cells that were significantly irrigated in 2000 are assigned their irrigated yield potential (we model the 2000 irrigation patterns instead of using the observed pattern to keep comparisons between 2000 and 2015 consistent). In addition, some arable cells in each country not in cropland as of 2000 but that closely resemble their country's irrigated cells as of 2000 are given their irrigated rather than rainfed yield potential. How similar these arable cells have to be to those that were significantly irrigated in 2000 to receive their irrigated yield potential is determined for each country by the modeler (SI Text 1). The less strict the resemblance required, the greater the number of arable cells in a country that are assigned their irrigated yield potential. In the end, if irrigation infrastructure and technology is not implemented in the pattern assumed by our cropland suitability layer then the spatial allocation of cropland expansion and modeled relative change in cropland productivity will be inaccurate, especially in those countries expected to rely heavily on irrigation to fuel their crop production growth (see Table S1 for country-by-country estimates of growth in cropland grid cell area that will benefit to some degree by irrigation under both scenarios).

While we assume that cropland output in a cell is solely a function of its productive potential and access to water, there are many other factors that affect the productivity of cropped areas, including infrastructure designed to support agriculture. For example, Vera-Diaz et al. show that soybean yields are higher, all else equal, if the farmer has access to markets via roads [74]. They surmise that farmers invest more of their time and capital in cropping operations if they can easily market their product. Presumably such infrastructure has been established in areas where cropland has existed for sometime. Newly established croplands, however, may not have the infrastructure necessary to support maximum production effort. Therefore, the InVEST agriculture production model includes a term that adjusts production on newer croplands according to infrastructure capacity and other factors (e.g., experimentation with fertilization rates to find the most cost-effective application) that might prevent maximum production capacity immediately. However, we do not use this term it in this illustrative example due to a lack of global data on the relationship between agriculture infrastructure and yields.

It is also possible that arable area around the globe could be expanded in the future. For example, draining low-lying areas (e.g., polders in the Netherlands) can increase the base of arable land. Conversion of existing agricultural to urban land and increased demand for food from a growing population will increase the incentive to make such investments. However, we lacked systematic data on which to base an assessment of an expansion of arable land base through investment and so did not include this dynamic in our analysis.

We use the carbon sequestration InVEST model to measure the change in biomass carbon storage (carbon sequestration) in each grid cell due to LULC change. First, we find average biomass carbon storage levels for each LULC type for each country using mapped Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change storage data and the 2000 LULC map. Second, we apply these average storage values to the maps of LULC in 2000 and 2015. The difference in each grid cell's storage value between 2000 and 2015 gives a gridded map of change in storage. (Because it can take decades for a LULC type to reach its average biomass carbon storage level we do not technically measure actual biomass carbon sequestration over the 2000 to 2015 period; instead we measure the eventual change in biomass carbon storage if the 2015 global LULC map were maintained indefinitely.) Our application of the InVEST sequestration model does not account for biomass carbon flux in grid cells that do not experience a LULC change, it does not account for carbon flux due to land management, and we do not attempt to adjust storage capacities and sequestration rates due to expected climate change. We summarize biomass carbon sequestration results by country under both scenarios.

We also measure the conversion of undeveloped land by ecoregion [75], [76]. In our analysis we make the simplifying assumption that undeveloped land – all LULC types other than urban and cropland – is more likely to provide habitat for species than urban and cropland area. Therefore, changes in undeveloped land area are correlated with change in species habitat. (Our inability to translate mapped land covers into habitat types and a lack of a comprehensive, global dataset on species-land cover suitabilities makes it impossible for us to model changes in global habitat; see the Discussion section for more details.) To identify which scenario is more detrimental to species persistence we summarize loss of undeveloped land area at the ecoregion level and then cross-walk these losses against measures of ecoregion habitat availability, habitat connectivity, and numbers of endangered and threatened species.

We combine projections in LULC change and carbon storage maps to make a contribution to the recent policy discussions on REDD. Under REDD or some similar avoided emissions policy, countries that reduce deforestation or forest degradation below some business-as-usual rate would generate avoided carbon emission credits that could be sold to entities looking to reduce their carbon emission liabilities. LULC change scenarios that do not assume a REDD policy, like those presented here, could be used by policy makers to predict business-as-usual country-level deforestation and associated emissions rates. To simulate a representative avoided deforestation global policy illustrate this process, we estimate the area of forest in each country that is cleared under a scenario but, given a sufficient avoided deforestation payment, would have generated more in economic returns by accepting the avoided deforestation payment than converting to the projected land use (subject to a country cap on avoided emission credits that is a function of historic deforestation rates [77]). Because we assume the economic value of urban expansion will always be greater than the value of any avoided emission credit, avoided deforestation and credit generation only occurs in grid cells where cropland is predicted to emerge from forest between 2000 and 2015 but the value of the credit is greater than the expected value of the new cropland. We summarize avoided emission results by country under both scenarios. (Obviously, if the avoided deforestation policy was implemented as given and occurred as modeled then changes in crop production, water yield, biomass carbon emissions, and loss in undeveloped land from 2000 to 2015 would be different than given here.)

We order country-level results according to a measure of human development, the 2006 Human Development Index (HDI; [78]). We do this to identify the spatial correlations between patterns of global change and current human well-being [5], [79]. HDI, which ranges from 0 to 1 where higher scores indicate greater overall human well-being in a country, is a composite measure of a country's life expectancy, educational attainment, and per capita GDP. HDI scores are often ranked in descending order where the country with the highest HDI has a ranking of 1.

Results

Urbanization and cropland grid cell area change

We plot cumulative country-level net change in urban and cropland grid cell area between 2000 and 2015 from lowest to highest HDI score (Figure 1). The area of grid cells classified as urban expands by 0.76 million km2, roughly the size of Turkey (expansion in urban grid cell area does not equal expansion in urban area as many grid cells that are primarily urban will include some other land covers as well). Depending on the scenario, global cropland grid cell area is expected to expand by 1.48 to 1.88 million km2 over this time period, roughly the size of Iran and Libya, respectively (again, expansion in cropland grid cell area does not equal expansion in croplands as many grid cells that are primarily cropland will include some other land covers as well). This graph understates the amount of new cropland grid cell area that will emerge across the globe as additional cropland will be needed to compensate for the cropland that existed as of 2000 but converts to urban area as of 2015. Most of the growth in cropland is located in the least-developed countries (Brazil and Libya under the regional scenario are the exceptions).

thumbnail
Figure 1. Projected net change in global urban and cropland grid cell area from 2000 to 2015.

Country-level contribution to projected global net change in urban and cropland grid cell area is sorted by 2006 Human Development Index (HDI) rank. There is one projection of urban grid cell area change and two projections of cropland grid cell area change (the country and regional scenarios). The graph also indicates urban grid cell area that was established between 2000 and 2015 on cropland grid cells. The portions of the cropland grid cell area curves that decline indicate countries expected to experience a net decline in cropland grid cell area. This graphic does not include the 0.007 million km2 gain in urban grid cell area in unclassified HDI countries. This graphic does not include the 0.03 and 0.07 million km2 net gain in cropland grid cell area in unclassified HDI countries under the country and regional scenarios, respectively.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.g001

Crop production services

Change in harvested area strongly mirrors change in cropland grid cell area; however, it is not a perfect predictor of change in harvested hectares due to differences across the globe in cropping intensity, fallow practices, and the matrix of land used for other purposes in grid cells designated as cropland (see the Methods and Materials section for information on how we converted change in cropland grid cell area to change in harvested hectares). Like the change in cropland grid cell area, net growth in harvested hectares in countries with low HDI scores is stronger under both scenarios (panel A of Figure 2). These results are consistent with expectations that developing countries will produce an increasing share of the world's crops in the future [7]. As with the graph of the net change in cropland grid cell area, this graph understates the amount of new harvested area that will emerge across the globe as additional harvested area will be needed to compensate for the harvested area that existed as of 2000 but is converted to urban area by 2015.

thumbnail
Figure 2. Projected net change in global harvested area and crop production from 2000 to 2015.

Country-level contribution to projected global net change in harvested area (panel A) and crop production measured in mass (panel B) and calories (panel C) is sorted by 2006 HDI rank for both scenarios. Countries projected to experience significant changes are noted. For panels B and C scenario results are given once assuming each country's 2000 crop mix remains as of 2015 (“The 2000 Crop Mix”) and once assuming 2015 crop mixes mimic forecasted trends in crop mix (“Projected 2015 Crop Mix”). By crop mix we mean the relative amount of harvested area devoted to each crop type (e.g., rice, wheat, oil crops, etc.) in a country. Panel C does not include a country's production of crops in the categories fiber crops, oil seeds, and other oil crops. The portions of the curves that decline indicate countries expected to experience a net decline in crop production on the given metric. This graphic does not include the net gain in harvested area and crop production in unclassified HDI countries.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.g002

While growth in harvested area can be a significant driver of economic growth in an area [80], change in crop production most directly impacts human well-being. All else equal, a net increase in area devoted to crop production in a country will increase its output over time (whether measured in mass or calories). In addition, a country's production will get a boost over time if it grows crops that are expected to experience yield increases due to improvements in agricultural methods and technology. Production levels in a country can also be positively affected by certain patterns of cropland change; namely, if a country's 2015 pattern of cropped area covers grid cells that, on average, have greater yield potential than the cropped area in 2000 then, all else equal, production will increase. A change in a country's crop mix between 2000 and 2015 also affects production (by crop mix we mean the relative amount of harvested hectares devoted to each crop type, e.g., rice, wheat, oil crops, etc., in a country). If a country switches to more dense crops, either in terms of mass or calories, then, all else equal, its production (as measured by mass or calories) will increase. If a country switches towards crops whose yields are improving due to technology managerial improvements then, all else equal, its production (as measured by mass or calories) will increase.

In panel B of Figure 2 we present modeled change in the mass of crop production by country, once under the assumption that the 2015 crop mix in a country mimics its 2000 mix (labeled “2000 Crop Mix”) and another time under the assumption that country-level crop mixes as of 2015 are more in line with forecasts from [7] (labeled “Projected 2015 Crop Mix”). In Table 1 we present more detailed information on the modeled changes in the mass of production at the country-level under the assumption that the 2015 crop mix in a country mimics its 2000 mix. In this case the increase in the mass of crop production in countries with low HDI (0 to 0.5) is primarily due to the increase in cropped area (and any improvements due to a potentially more productive pattern of cropland) while the increase in the mass of crop production in countries with medium and high HDI (0.5 to 0.8 and 0.8 to 1, respectively) is increasingly explained by improved yields, either due to technological improvement, increased irrigation capacity, the use of more productive land, or all three. Change in the mass of production in low and medium HDI countries is more efficient under the regional scenario (as measured by the ratio of change in net output to net change in harvested area). This result reflects the fact that the cellular modeling technique generally has more freedom to choose the most suitable cropland grid cells under the regional scenario than it does under the country scenario (i.e., the cellular model is allocating over a region rather than a country). However, because abandonment of cropland area in the highest HDI countries (nations with better access to technological improvements in the agricultural sector) is much smaller under the country scenario, the difference in crop production growth between the scenarios is small despite the regional scenario's additional 0.19 million harvested km2 (by 2015 the mass of crop production under the country scenario is 10.3% greater than 2000 modeled production whereas the gain is 11.2% under the regional scenario). In Table 2 we present information on the ratio of change in net output to net change in harvested area when we use 2015 country-level crop mixes that are more in line with forecasts from [7]. While the trends across HDI groups that we observed in Table 1 are similar, the global change in the mass of crop production under the country and regional scenarios are significantly lower, 1.5% and 1.7%, respectively. In other words, future crop mixes are forecasted to be much lighter from a mass perspective than the mixes found in 2000.

thumbnail
Table 1. Change in the mass of crop production between 2000 and 2015 assuming country-level crop mixes in 2015 mimic those observed in 2000.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.t001

thumbnail
Table 2. Change in the mass of crop production between 2000 and 2015 using 2015 projected country-level crop mixes in 2015.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.t002

While measuring crop production by mass is appropriate for economic analyses of production, measuring production in calories is a better indicator of the value that crop production provides to human well-being [81]. If we convert crop production from mass units to calories [82] global production under the projected 2015 crop mix [7] outperforms the 2000 mix in both scenarios (panel C of Figure 2 and Table 3; we exclude oil and fiber crops from the analysis). The superiority of the projected crop mix in caloric terms again suggests that lighter but more energy dense grains are expected to become more and more dominant in global food production. Further, the country scenario now outperforms the regional scenario on the global crop production metric. This suggests that the expansion of global harvested area under the country scenario tends to occur in countries expected to experience more significant yield growth in grains.

thumbnail
Table 3. Change in the caloric value of crop production between 2000 and 2015.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.t003

Whether the projected increase in calorie production is adequate to meet expanding human demand, both as food consumed directly and as feed for livestock, is uncertain. Global population is projected to increase by 19.1% from 2000 to 2015 [8] while caloric production in crops is expected to increase from 16.0% to 23.8% (the regional scenario with the 2000 crop mix and the country scenario with the projected 2015 crop mix; calorie growth does not include the growth in the production of meat, eggs, and milk from livestock supported by pasture and rangeland vegetation). However, even if global caloric output is sufficient to keep pace with population, pockets of malnourishment are likely to persist due to uneven distribution of crop production across regions [83].

Annual water yield on rainfed cropland

Whether there will be sufficient water to support all modeled growth in crop production is a major concern. To begin to explore this issue we plot country-level changes in rainfed cropland grid cell area (cropland in cells assigned the potential rainfed yield on the cropland suitability layer) versus the projected change in average annual water yield on rainfed cropland grid cells (Figure 3). Production on rainfed cropland is limited by water produced directly on the cropland and cannot be maintained by irrigation. Therefore, our projections for crop production growth may be too high in countries that are projected to expand rainfed cropland area but experience, on average, a decline in annual water availability (the lower right quadrant of the graphs in Figure 3 indicates countries with such a tradeoff). There are five more countries in the lower right quadrant under the regional scenario (panel B) than in the country scenario (panel A). Further, projected rainfed cropland expansion is quite dramatic in several of these at-risk countries under the regional scenario (see Tables 4 and 5 for a list of all countries in the lower right quadrants of the graphs in Figure 3).

thumbnail
Figure 3. Projected relative change in rainfed cropland grid cell area versus relative change in average annual water yield on rainfed cropland grid cells.

Panel A gives results for the country scenario. Panel B gives results for the regional scenario. Each point represents a country. A high development country (“High Dev.”) has a 2006 HDI greater than or equal to 0.8, a middle development country (“Middle Dev.”) has a 2006 HDI greater than or equal to 0.5 but less than 0.8, a low development country (“Low Dev.”) has a 2006 HDI less then 0.5, and a unclassified country has no HDI score. We indicate the number of countries (N) and the average HDI score (HD) of those countries in each quadrant in each graph.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.g003

thumbnail
Table 4. Countries where rainfed cropland area increases but average annual water yield on rainfed cropland area decreases between 2000 and 2015 under the country scenario (the lower right quadrant of panel A in Figure 3).

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.t004

thumbnail
Table 5. Countries where rainfed cropland area increases but average annual water yield on rainfed cropland area decreases under the regional scenario (the lower right quadrant of panel B in Figure 3).

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.t005

Despite having more countries where, on average, water yield on rainfed cropland grid cells is decreasing while the area of rainfed cropland grid cells is increasing, from a global perspective the expansion in rainfed cropland under the regional scenario is slightly better aligned with expected changes in annual water yield patterns than the country scenario. In 2000, average annual water yield on all rainfed cropland grid cells across the globe was estimated to be 636 mm km−2. In 2015, the average yield is projected to be 645 mm km−2 under the regional scenario and 632 mm km−2 under the country scenario. Maps of expected changes in water availability on rainfed cropland around the globe and for two regions of the world across the two scenarios are shown in Figures 4 and 5.

thumbnail
Figure 4. Projected change in average annual water yield from 2000 to 2015 on 2015 rainfed cropland grid cells around the globe (mm km−2).

The map on the left gives results for the country scenario while the map on the right gives results for the regional scenario. White areas on a map either mean there is no change in water yield over time or the area is not identified as a rainfed cropland grid cell as of 2015.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.g004

thumbnail
Figure 5. Projected change in average annual water yield from 2000 to 2015 on 2015 rainfed cropland grid cells for two regions (mm km−2).

The maps on the left give results for the country scenario while the maps on the right give results for the regional scenario. White areas on a map either mean there is no change in water yield over time or the area is not identified as a rainfed cropland grid cell as of 2015.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.g005

Biomass carbon emissions due to land conversion

Cumulative country-level changes in biomass carbon storage due to land conversion is sorted by HDI rank (Figure 6). Most of the difference between the two scenarios is explained by the projected loss of broadleaved forest area in Brazil (Figure S1). Under the regional scenario, 0.84 million km2 of additional broadleaved forest are lost between 2000 and 2015 in Brazil when compared to country scenario. Other than Brazil, most of the net loss in biomass carbon occurs in countries with HDI ranks of less than 100 (the least-developed countries). Some countries with high HDI show a net gain in biomass carbon storage because their cropland abandonment rates are close to or even outpace their urban growth rates.

thumbnail
Figure 6. Projected net change in global biomass carbon storage (sequestration) due to land conversion.

Country-level contribution to the projected global change in biomass carbon storage (sequestration) is sorted by HDI rank. The portions of the curve that increase indicate countries expected to experience a net gain in storage due to LULC change. Countries projected to experience significant changes are noted. This graphic does not include the 0.0008 and 0.0005 billion Mg net loss in biomass carbon storage due to land conversion in unclassified HDI countries under the country and regional scenarios, respectively.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.g006

Loss in undeveloped land and species persistence

Global cropland and urban area expansion reduces the global supply of undeveloped land (non-urban and non-cropland covers), a land type that is more likely to provide species habitat than other land uses. In Figure 7 we summarize the gross conversion of global undeveloped grid cell area by ecoregion conservation status and scenario (by gross we mean that we do not include cropland that is abandoned to less intensive uses). An ecoregion's conservation status indicates the degree of habitat alternation and spatial pattern of remaining habitat in an ecoregion at the end of the 20th century [84]. Critical and endangered ecoregions retain little natural habitat and the habitat that remains is highly fragmented and the continued persistence of many species is highly uncertain. Vulnerable and relatively stable ecoregions are less disturbed. While the regional scenario converts more undeveloped grid cell area over the 15 year period (3.2 versus 2.7 million km2), the country scenario converts more undeveloped grid cell area in the most endangered ecoregions (1.6 versus 1.2 million km2 in critical/endangered ecoregions).

thumbnail
Figure 7. Projected global change in undeveloped land area from 2000 to 2015 by ecoregion status.

Each bar indicates the loss of undeveloped land area by vegetation type [109]. See the text and [84] for more information on ecoregion status. In this graph we do not include any undeveloped land area provided by cropland abandonment from 2000 to 2015.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.g007

We also plot each ecoregion's net relative change in undeveloped grid cell area versus the percentage of the ecoregion's species that are critically endangered/endangered according to the IUCN Red List by HDI category [75], [85] (Figure 8). An ecoregion can experience a net grid cell area increase in undeveloped land if its growth in abandoned cropland grid cell area (not including the cropland abandoned to urban use) is greater than its loss of undeveloped land to urban and cropland grid cell area [86]. While all ecoregions in low development countries show net loses in undeveloped land across both scenarios, none of these ecoregions are particularly rich in critically endangered/endangered species when compared to some ecoregions in the middle and high development countries. Finally, Figure 8 indicates that many more ecoregions in middle and high development countries are projected to experience a net loss in undeveloped grid cell area under the country scenario than under the regional scenario. However, particularly large losses of undeveloped land in the Madeira-Tapajós moist forests (Amazon Basin), Southwest Amazon moist forests, Uatuma-Trombetas moist forests (Amazon Basin), and Kazakh steppe ecoregions under the regional scenario account for that scenario's greater conversion of undeveloped land around the world as indicated by Figure 7.

thumbnail
Figure 8. Projected global change in undeveloped land area versus species endangerment status by ecoregion.

Each circle represents an ecoregion. The two numbers in each quadrant (defined by 0.1 on the y-axis and 0 on the x-axis) in each graph indicate the number of ecoregions in a quadrant under the country and regional scenarios. Change in undeveloped land area is a net measure because we assume abandoned cropland that does not convert to urban area becomes undeveloped land. Data on an ecoregion's fraction of critically endangered and endangered species comes from [75].

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.g008

Avoided emissions analysis

In Figure 9 we summarize avoided emissions assuming a REDD-like program existed as of 2000 and that our scenarios were used by program administrators to determine business-as-usual deforestation and associated carbon emissions rates. We determine avoided emissions for two avoided deforestation credit prices, $5 and $150 Mg−1 per emissions of CO2e (carbon dioxide-equivalent) avoided. The regional scenario, which had more than twice the loss of stored biomass carbon than the country scenario, generates far more avoided emission credits. In this illustration, avoided emissions supply is barely affected by offset price; $5 offsets generate almost as much avoided emissions as do $150 offsets. This result occurs because the net returns to agriculture are, on average, very low in Brazil, the source of most credits under both scenarios. This suggests that, assuming transaction and other program costs are kept low, modestly priced carbon offsets could prevent an aggressive acceleration in agricultural development in Brazil.

thumbnail
Figure 9. Projected avoided biomass carbon emissions due to an avoided emissions program.

Expected country-level contribution to avoided global biomass carbon emissions at offset credit prices of $5 and $150 Mg−1 of CO2-e is sorted by HDI rank. Brazil's contribution is noted on the graph.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.g009

Tradeoffs

To summarize, we observe a tradeoff among LULC change and ecosystem service and species habitat provision from 2000 to 2015. The tradeoff is less severe under the country scenario. Specifically, the grams of carbon released due to LULC conversion per additional calorie of crop produced is 62% less and the loss of undeveloped area (our proxy for species habitat) per additional calorie of crop produced is 24% less under the country scenario when compared to the regional scenario. The country scenario's more efficient production of calories relies heavily on a 1) fairly dramatic expansion in irrigation capacity, 2) greater cropland expansion in countries with greater access to technological improvements in agriculture, and 3) avoidance of large-scale land conversion in important biomass carbon storage areas. The regional scenario outperforms the country scenario on only one modeled metric: rainfed cropland under the country scenario is expected to receive less water than it is under the regional scenario. Therefore, if 1) the relatively heavy expansion in irrigation capacity that underpins the country scenario's results does not occur as modeled and 2) the greater water shortages on rainfed cropland under the country scenario significantly impairs rainfed cropland productivity then the tradeoff gap between the two scenarios would shrink.

Discussion

In this paper we demonstrate a straightforward method for allocating expected LULC change given at a spatially coarse level to a grid cell-level and predicting the impacts of such mapped change on the provision of several ecosystem services and habitat (see Text S1 for a comparison of projected changes to actual changes that have occurred since 2000). Our spatial allocation method is a cellular process that is guided by maps that describe how well-suited each grid cell is to a particular land use. We then use the InVEST methodology to translate LULC changes into changes in the provision of various ecosystem services and undeveloped land (our proxy for species habitat). This approach is transparent and well suited to cases where data and technical expertise are limited.

In our illustration of this approach we are temporally modest. We only project to 2015 for several reasons. First, there are global projections for regional agricultural land use and grid cell-level population density out to 2015. Further, extrapolating country-level trends in cropland over a 20-year period (the mid 1990s to the mid 2010s) seems reasonable. Second, by only projecting to 2015 we minimize the bias in our models caused by our present inability to more comprehensively incorporate impacts of climate change and other dynamic feedback effects (see below). However, we feel our approach is also well-suited for the exploration of the global impacts of much more distant future scenarios. In such analyses, expectations for country- or regional-level land-use change would not be based on well-calibrated models' projections for the near future but on plausible global change trajectories. For example, what would the pattern and magnitude of environmental impact be across the globe if the developing world adopted the current diet preferences of the developed world by 2060? It has been estimated that such a future would require an additional 26 million km2 of cropland compared to year 2000 levels (approximately the combined area of Canada and Russia; personal communication with David Tilman). Using various plausible cropland suitability maps and cellular allocation processes consistent with basic economic theory and broad expectations for changes in climate, technology, population and consumer preferences, we could create several global maps of LULC that might meet such a goal and calculate each projection's impact on ecosystem service and habitat provision. For example, one alternative cropland suitability layer in this analysis could relax the restriction on cropland development in protected areas according to data on the effectiveness of protected area management [87]. Identification of the preferred cropland development path and the policy levers necessary to get to the preferred change path could follow.

This potential for our methodology to inform land-use and ecosystem service provision policies, either in the short or long-term, is particularly exciting. For example, cropland suitability scores could be increased in grid cells in parts of the world that governments have targeted for cropland expansion or agricultural subsidies. The ecosystem service ramifications of these spatially-explicit policies could then be estimated and compared to business-as-usual development patters. In this paper we illustrate how one could use LULC change projections to establish a baseline of deforestation to set eligibility and cap requirements in a global REDD-like program instead of relying on historic deforestation rates [88]. Using projected LULC maps instead of historic deforestation rates to guide a global REDD-like program avoids the perverse result of rewarding countries that aggressively deforested in the immediate past. Finally, as noted above, policy makers could use this tool to begin a discussion on the more distant future and the impact that another 50 or 100 years of development might have on the earth's environment.

Potential improvements in our methodology

The general approach described here can be improved in a number of ways. As of 2000, approximately 12% of the earth's land surface was used for cultivation while 22% was used for pastures and rangelands [89]. Growing global demand for meat would suggest additional forest and natural grasslands will be converted to pasture and rangeland, especially in Africa and Latin America [90]. We do not currently account for such land conversion in our scenarios, primarily due to inadequate data on current and expected pasture land area in many regions of the world. Including pasture land as an explicit LULC category, modeling its change, and its impact on ecosystem services and habitat would no doubt improve our general approach. However, we do not believe that ignoring pasture change significantly compromises our general approach, especially given the world's increasing reliance on confined livestock production (in 2003, 70% of developed countries' consumption of meat, milk, and eggs came from livestock largely raised in confined settings) [90, personal communication with David Tilman]. Confined livestock production is largely supported by grains, not pasture. This suggests that most new agricultural land around the globe in the future will be devoted to crop production rather than grass production.

The lack of pasture land in our model is not the only LULC change dynamic missing from our approach. In fact, any change in LULC that does not involve urban or cropland area is ignored (e.g., we do not account for forest to wetland transitions). Further, for the types of LULC change we do account for, we do not measure and spatially allocate all change, just the change necessary to spatially allocate net change. Therefore, our approach underestimates the amount and variety of LULC change around the world. Data limitations explain the absence of these LULC change dynamics from our approach. To illustrate our approach's limitations and the impact of these assumptions consider LULC change in the United States from 1992 to 2001. During that time period the US experienced a 400 km2 net gain in agricultural area (cropland, pasture, and rangeland area). In our approach we would have only worked with the cropland portion of this net change. However, assume our approach was modified to model change in agricultural area, not just cropland area. In our spatial allocation approach, after allocating the 7,200 km2 of urban area that emerged from cropland, pasture, and rangeland from 1992 to 2001, we would have spatially allocated 7,600 km2 of new cropland, pasture, and rangeland area over forest, wetland and grassland area to account for the net gain of 400 km2. However, during this 1992 to 2001 period 17,300 km2 of agricultural land was converted to forests, wetlands and grasslands; a LULC change dynamic our approach does not account for [91]. Therefore, if we were to model all LULC change, the 400 km2 net gain in agricultural land from 1992 to 2001 would include the conversion of 24,900 km2 of grassland, wetlands, and forests to agricultural uses and not just the 7,600 km2 we would have modeled (24,900 km2 less the 7,200 km2 of urban area that emerged from agricultural use and the 17,300 km2 of agricultural lands lost to other uses generates a net gain of 400 km2).

The approach in this paper uses potential cereal yield under intensive management as a proxy for cropland suitability. Suitability layers that incorporate regional crop and crop production mixes could be developed. These more nuanced layers could also incorporate other factors that affect crop and management choice including proximity to markets and transportation networks, local crop prices, local policies and land tenure issues, production costs, and consideration of crop failure risks [4], [74], [92][97]. The proper combination of all of this data would generate suitability layers that measure the expected net revenues from farming in each grid cell. Such net revenue layers would improve our analysis in several respects. First, it would lead to more accurate predictions of where crops would be grown and therefore, the effect of cropland expansion on ecosystem service and habitat provision. As we have shown here the spatial allocation of cropland can have a major effect on biomass carbon emissions and habitat provision and also significantly impact water quality, soil conservation, and nutrient cycles [5], [93], [98]. Second, such suitability layers would improve the analyses of policies that are a function of land-based opportunity cost. For example, in our avoided emission analysis we assign a country's average net revenue from cropland to each cropland grid cell in the country instead of grid cell-specific estimates. Using one estimate of cropland net revenues across a whole country means for a given carbon credit price that either all or none of the eligible grid cells in the country will avoid deforestation (“bang-bang” solutions). In reality, the forested areas that would generate the lowest returns in cropland as of 2015, the areas where payments for avoided deforestation would make the most economic sense, are scattered across the globe. A lack of data prevents us from creating a cropland suitability map based on net revenues. While crop yield and basic agriculture management data from across the globe are becoming more readily available, globally available data on production and related costs, country-level policies and land tenure issues, and crop production uncertainties are lacking [99], [100].

In this paper we only use a few of the InVEST ecosystem service models and the ones that are presented are the simplest versions available. For example, InVEST includes water quality, soil conservation, and agricultural greenhouse gas emissions models that could be applied to our scenarios. However, to use these models we would first have to create global maps of chemical use and land-management. Further, with better data we could have used more sophisticated InVEST models in this analysis. For example, in the simple habitat model used here we assume all undeveloped area provide habitat of some sort to species. More precisely, by aggregating all undeveloped area in an ecoregion we are implicitly assuming that undeveloped land provides habitat of the same quality to all species. However, habitat closer to urban areas and croplands may not be able to support species to the same degree than more isolated habitat can [101]. Further, not all undeveloped land will be suitable to all species; a suitable cover for one species may not be usable by another. InVEST contains a model that allows us to adjust habitat quality based on proximity to disturbances and ecosystem type. However, this analysis requires additional work to identify and map threats and habitat preferences of species guilds by ecoregion. Finally, as an alternative to InVEST, we could have combined our predictions of global LULC change with more complex water models and carbon models such as SWAT and CENTURY [102][104]. These models, however, tend to require sophisticated users and detailed data and are designed to work at the regional scale; these characteristics will likely restrict their applicability with more general analyses and in many regions.

Another important limitation in our analysis, and almost all current work on LULC and ecosystem services and habitat provision change, is the lack of adequate treatment of dynamic feedbacks and thresholds [56]. For example, our model does not consider how cropland pattern and use will respond to climate change, changes in availability of inputs, or changes in technology. Farmers could adapt to changes in climate by changing crop choice, improving input management, adopting water saving technologies such as drip irrigation, or simply relocating. Such changes, however, may take many years and involve large sunk costs and significant learning [105], [106]. Changes in climate will also affect urban development patterns [107]. Potential threshold events associated with climate change are also not included. Further, we do not consider technological or biophysical thresholds that may create abrupt changes in service provision by ecosystems. For example nutrient loadings may cause estuaries and freshwater systems to undergo abrupt change [108]. By projecting LULC change and associated impacts on ecosystem service delivery to 2015 we minimize the bias in our models caused by our present inability to more comprehensively incorporate impacts of climate change and other dynamic feedback effects.

Materials and Methods

Spatially allocating 2000 to 2015 urbanization

We begin with a gridded map of the globe from 2000 where each grid cell is assigned a LULC (the cells are 5 km×5 km at the equator, see Text S1; [109], [110]). In each country we convert grid cells into urban use such that the projected 2000 to 2015 increase in urban grid cell area in the country is met [8]. Let , , and indicate grid cell area in urban use in country j in 2000, grid cell area in urban use in country j in 2015, and net change in urban area in country j from 2000 to 2015, respectively (Table S2). is never less than 0.

To spatially allocate we use an urban suitability map and a land-use change simulation module for the Idrisi Andes geographic information system called GEOMOD [58], [59]. in the change simulation GEOMOD tends to convert grid cells that have higher urban suitability scores and are in close proximity to existing urban grid cells into urban use. A GEOMOD simulation runs in annual time steps such that a portion of is allocated each year from 2000 to 2015 until all of has been allocated by 2015. We assume grid cells that are projected to have higher 2015 population densities [60] and that are flatter [61] are the most suitable for urban use. Specifically, grid cells with slopes of less than 12% receive values of 5, between 12 and 18% receive values of 4, between 18 and 30% receive values of 3, between 30 and 50% receive values of 2, and 50% or greater receive values of 1. Further, grid cells with a predicted 2015 population density of zero receive values of 1 and values greater than zero receive values ranging from 2–5 using an equal interval system where areas with higher predicted densities are given scores closer to five. A grid cell's suitability score is the average of its scores on the two metrics. GEOMOD uses suitability layers on a scale of 0 to 100. Therefore the program converts the urban suitability map from the 1 to 5 scale to a 0 to 100 scale before it runs the land-use change simulation (Figure S2). Grid cells that are in protected areas as of 2000 (IUCN categories of I through VI category) are not eligible for urban land use in 2015 [62]. See Text S1 for more information on the calculation of , , and and the spatial allocation of .

Cropland grid cells, cropland area, and harvested area in 2000

We designate each grid cell on the 2000 LULC map in the covers “Cultivated and managed areas”, “Mosaic: Cropland/Tree Cover/Other natural vegetation”, and “Mosaic: Cropland/Shrub or Grass Cover” as cropland [109], [110]. We use the term cropland grid cell area to refer to the aggregate area of grid cells designated as cropland. Let Cj and Cr indicate the cropland grid cell area in country j and region r, respectively, on the 2000 LULC map. There are 25.4 million km2 of cropland grid cell area on the 2000 global LULC map. As suggested by the cover names that we collectively refer to as cropland, these cells can contain a mix of other LULC, including pasture, roads, villages, etc. Hereafter we use the term cropland area to refer to the area in cropland grid cells actually used to grow crops. (Cropland area includes land under temporary crops (double-cropped areas are counted only once), temporary meadows for mowing or pasture, land under market and kitchen gardens and land temporarily fallow. The abandoned land resulting from shifting cultivation is not included. This estimate also includes crops that occupy the land for some years and need not be replanted after each annual harvest, such as cocoa, coffee and rubber. This category includes flowering shrubs, fruit trees, nut trees and vines, but excludes trees grown for wood or timber.)

In any given year not all cropland area produces cropped output because of fallow practices and crop failures. Conversely, some cropped areas are used multiple times in a calendar year. Let the area of crop production used over the course of a year be known as harvested area. Let Hj and Hr indicate the estimate of harvested area in 2000 in country j and region r, respectively where croplands that produced crops multiple times in 2000 are double or triple counted (e.g., if X km2 of cropland in a country produced one crop in 2000 and if Y km2 of cropland in the country produced two crops in 2000 then the country's harvested hectares in 2000 are X+2Y) [6].

Calculating and spatially allocating net change in cropland grid cell area

We estimate changes in cropland area around the globe between 2000 and 2015 twice. In the country scenario we extrapolate 1985 to 2000 cropland area change rates at the country-level out to 2015 [6]. In the regional scenario we use [7] 's predictions of regional-level 2015 cropland area for major crops to determine rates of cropland area change at the region-level (see Table S3 for a list of countries by region). Let the rate of change in cropland area from 2000 to 2015 in country j or region r be given by or where (<1) indicates a net increase (a net decrease) in cropland area from 2000 to 2015.

The cropland grid cell area in country j and region r in 2015 under the country and regional scenarios are given by and , respectively,(1)(2)where and are j's and r's total arable grid cell area, respectively (Michael Jennings, personal communication). Arable area does not include urban grid cells in 2000 and 2015 and grid cells in protected areas as of 2000. By using equations (1) and (2) to project 2015 cropland grid cell area we assume that a country or region's cropland grid cell area will expand (or contract) at the same rate as the country or region's growth in cropland area. In other words, we assume that, on average, the density of cropland area within a country or region's cropland grid cell area is the same in 2015 as it was in 2000.

If a country or region is expected to experience a net gain in cropland grid cell area between 2000 and 2015, we decompose and into cropland grid cell area established between 2000 and 2015, , and cropland grid cell area established before 2000 but remains on the land as of 2015, , with the following system of equations,(3)(4)(5)where CU is the cropland grid cell area as of 2000 (C) that converted to urban land between 2000 and 2015 in country j or region r. Otherwise, if a country or region is expected to experience a net decrease in cropland grid cell area between 2000 and 2015 then C gives the net cropland grid cell area lost between 2000 and 2015. In such cases and if or and otherwise. Lost cropland grid cells either convert to urban use or become abandoned cropland with landcover equal to the dominant vegetation cover in the cell's ecoregion.

Using GEOMOD and the cropland suitability map we spatially allocate from the country scenario in each j given the already allocated expansion in urban grid cells. Again this is done in annual time steps such that all grid cells are allocated by 2015. Cells in urban use in 2000 or 2015, not in j's arable land zone, or in protected areas are not available for cropland use in 2015. If county j is projected to experience a loss in cropland grid cell area beyond that which is converted to urban use, then cropland cells with the lowest cropland suitability scores tend to be removed from the landscape by the simulation method. See Table S4 for country scenario results. We repeat the cropland grid cell allocation process on the global map with already allocated expansion in urban grid cells for each region under the regional scenario (Text S1, see Tables S5S6). After all of this we have two global 2015 LULC maps where the pattern of urbanization on both maps is the same and grid cells that did not urbanize or convert to or from cropland remain in their 2000 LULC.

The cropland suitability map is a function of slope [61] and potential cereal yield under intensive management [63] where grid cells with gentler slopes and higher potential yield are given higher suitability scores. When constructing the potential yield map we had to choose between the rainfed and irrigated potential cereal yield in each cell. We assign the irrigated yield to the cells in j that have potential yield characteristics that are correlated with the potential yield characteristics of grid cells with high irrigation use in j as of 2000 (as measured by percentage of cell irrigated; 18% of global cropland (2.79 million km2) was equipped for irrigation in 2000; see [73], Text S1, Figure S3, Tables S7S8). In other words, the irrigation model tends to select the irrigated potential yield for cells that were highly irrigated as of 2000 and those that were not cropland as of 2000 but had potential yield combinations that were very similar to those that were highly irrigated in 2000. A cell's suitability score was the average of its slope and potential yield scores. As before, GEOMOD converted suitability scores from a 1 to 5 scale to a 0 to 100 scale before simulating change (Text S1, Figures S4S5).

Calculating harvested area in 2015

Next we convert 2015 cropland grid cell area in a country into 2015 harvested area in the country. Expected harvested area in 2015 in country j is given by ,(6)where gives the fraction of j's grid cell cropland area in a single cropping zone in 2000, gives the fraction of j's grid cell cropland area in a double cropping zone in 2000, and and indicate the fraction of in single and double cropping zones in country j in 2015 ([63], Text S1, and Table S9). We calculate twice for each j, once under the country scenario and another time under the regional scenario (before using equation (6) with regional scenario estimates we convert , , and into , , and values). In equation (6) we assume that the harvested area in j expands at the same rate as the multi-cropping-weighted growth of cropland grid cell area in j. This means we assume that, on average, crop failure rates, fallow management, and cropping behavior in multiple cropping zones in a country will be the same in 2015 as it was in the country in 2000.

The harvested area established after 2000 in country j under a scenario is given by,(7)where the ‘n’ and ‘o’ in front of the Greek letters indicates the share of and , respectively, in the various cropping zones in 2015. Finally, harvested area in country j established prior to 2000 is given by,(8)

We calculate and twice for each j, once under the country scenario and another time under the regional scenario.

Measuring change in crop production between 2000 and 2015

To determine 2015 crop production in country j we first calculate each crop or crop types average yield in country j in 2000, given by Yji and measured in in Mg ha−1, where i = 1, 2, …, I includes individual crop types (e.g., rice) or crop groups (e.g., treenuts; [6], Text S1, and Table S10). For example, in 2000 96,000 hectares of maize and 124,000 hectares of barley were grown in Afghanistan; both crops belong to the coarse grains category (so do sorghum and oats, however, neither were produced in Afghanistan in 2000 according to [6]). Respective production was 114,998 Mg of maize and 73,991 Mg of barley. Therefore, coarse grain yield in Afghanistan in 2000 was 0.859 Mg ha−1 (i.e., 114,998 Mg + 73,991 Mg/96,000 ha +124,000 ha).

We determine the caloric production of crop type i in j in 2015 with,(9)where 1 is country j's expected 2000 to 2015 growth in i's yield due to technological change ([7], [65], Text S1, and Table S11); Ri is the average caloric content Mg−1 of crop or crop group i ([82], Text S1, and Table S12); and indicate the relative difference in the cropland productivity of the new and old cropland grid cells in 2015, respectively, versus the cropland grid cells in j as of 2000, the functions fn and fo convert and into yield inflators; indicates the fraction of “new” harvested hectares in j in crop or crop group i in 2015, [0,1] indicates the degree to which new harvested hectares used for crop or crop group i in j meets its projected productive capacity by 2015 where a 1 indicates it has reached its projected productive capacity; indicates the fraction of “old” harvested hectares in j that is in crop or crop group i in 2015; and . The first term in equation (9), , is an estimate of year 2000 ha−1 caloric production of crop or crop group i in country j and the second term converts this to 2015 levels given technology growth, changes in overall productivity of the grid cells used for crops, and crop mix changes. Relative changes in productivity, and , are given by relative changes in the suitability of cropland grid cell area in j. Specifically, the relative difference in the productivity of cropland grid cell area in 2015 versus 2000 in country j is found by dividing the 2015 average suitability score for new or old cropland grid cell area in j by the average suitability score for j's cropland cell area in 2000 (Text S1 and Table S13). For example, if the average cropland suitability score for new cropland grid cells in country j is 55 and the average agriculture suitability score for cropland grid cells in country j on the 2000 map is 49 then  = 55/49 = 1.12. For illustrative purposes we set for all j under both scenarios. The value of will depend on the crop or crop group, the land used for i in j, the technology applied to production for i in j, and agricultural-related infrastructure that can be accessed by the newly converted cropland in country j. Some lands will produce expected yields within a year or two of establishment while others may take a decade or more. Due to a lack of data we set in our model for all combinations of j and i. If we drop Ri from equation (9) then gives 2015 country-level production of crop or crop group i in metric tons. The change in the production of crop type i in j from 2000 to 2015 is given by and the change in all crop production in country j is given by .

We create 5 allocations of across all combinations of j and i. Let indicate the qth matrix of values. One realization of indicates the relative mix of crop types in each j as observed in 2000 (q = Year 2000 crop mix; [6], Text S1, and Table S14). In another projection we assume that the areal share of crop types other than rice, wheat, coarse grains, and oil seeds in each country will fall steeply by 2015 when compared to 2000 levels (q = 2; Text S1 and Table S15). In another we assume that the areal share of crop types other than rice, wheat, coarse grains, and oil seeds in each country will fall moderately by 2015 when compared to 2000 levels (q = 3; Text S1 and Table S16). In another we assume that the areal share of all crop types in each country will remain close to 2000 levels (q = 4; Text S1 and Table S17). In the last projection we set crop share values across countries such that the global area devoted to rice, wheat, coarse grains, and oil seeds matches that predicted by the agricultural trade model in [7] (q = Projected 2015 crop mix; [7], Text S1, and Table S18). In this illustration we set equal to ; there is no particular reason, however, why these must be equal.

Every input into equation (9) can be described with uncertainty. For example, for crop groups i we only use average yields and do not consider the observed distribution's other moments. Moreover, we do not consider how Yji of crop groups i will change over time due to changes in the areal mix of crops within the group. Nor do we consider how Yji might change as the climate changes, etc. Further, we assume that the effect of and on yields are given by the functional form; other functional forms are not experimented with. In addition, the values of and will be sensitive to variables other than the relative change in cropland suitability, including the specific allocation of crop types across j and water availability. The expected paths of agricultural technology development are also highly uncertain. We experiment a bit with alternative crop choice allocations, although the matrices and could be perturbed even more.

Annual water yield

Annual water yield, measured in mm km−2, is equal to the precipitation that falls during the course of a year less the water that evaporates or transpires (actual evapotranspiration) [2], [67][72].

Annual water yield in grid cell x In LULC j in 2000 is given by Wxj and in 2015 by . Hereafter we describe how to calculate Wxj. The variable is calculated in the same manner but with 2015 data, including LULC cover in grid cell x and precipitation in grid cell x. Let,(10)where AETxj is the annual actual evapotranspiration on grid cell x with LULC j in 2000 (measured in mm km−2) and Px is the year 2000 precipitation on grid cell x (measured in mm km−2). Therefore, Wxj represents the amount of water available to the surface and groundwater systems in x's watershed over the course of 2000.

The portion of equation (10) that represents evapotranspiration, AETx/Px, is an approximation of the Budyko curve,(11)where mx is the dimensionless ratio of plant accessible water storage to expected precipitation during the year and Rxj is the dimensionless Budyko Dryness index on grid cell x in 2000 and is defined as the ratio of potential evapotranspiration to precipitation [68], [70].

As defined by [70], mx is a non-physical parameter that characterizes the natural climatic-soil properties in grid cell x [69], [71], [72],(12)where AWCxj is the volumetric (mm) plant available water content on grid cell x in LULC j [111], a soil property generally estimated as the difference in water content (mm) between field capacity and wilting point (i.e., the amount of water that can be held and released in the soil for use by a plant), and Zx is a constant that is calibrated for climatically homogeneous basins (i.e., Z is the same for all grid cells in a climatically homogeneous basins). The soil texture and effective soil depth in grid cell x defines AWCx. The constant Z adjusts the water balance to account for timing differences of monthly intra-annual rainfall and energy distribution patterns, and rainfall intensities. Variation in m across a landscape reflects variation in available water content and rainfall across the landscape. Although we recognize that the relationship between w and AWC/P is technically non-linear, we assume a linear relationship to simplify modeling.

We define the Budyko dryness index as follows, (13)where ETox is the reference evapotranspiration on grid cell x [112], [113] and kxj is the plant evapotranspiration coefficient associated with the LULC j on grid cell x. ETo is an index of climatic demand while kxj is largely determined by j's vegetative characteristics [114]. Budyko dryness index values that are greater than one denote grid cells that are potentially arid [68].

We use the HadCM3 climate model with the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change A2 greenhouse-gas emissions scenario to map global annual precipitation [66]. Because global maps of precipitation under HadCM3 with the A2 emissions scenario are not available for 2000 and 2015 we use a modeled precipitation map from 1990 with the 2000 LULC map and a modeled precipitation map from 2025 with the 2015 LULC maps. Therefore, depending on the pace of climate change, our grid cell-level changes in annual water yield will deviate slightly from estimates we would have generated if we had been able to use 2000 and 2015 precipitation maps with the 2000 and 2015 LULC maps.

See Table S19 for data on average country-level water yield on rainfed cropland grid cells in 2000 and 2015 under both scenarios.

In our analysis we imply that a decline in average annual water yield in an area means that rainfed cropland yields in the area may not increase at the rate of technological growth, all else being equal (in addition, less runoff will be available for irrigation use). However, this may not be the case in a given area for several reasons. First, if an annual reduction in water yield in an area is primarily due to reductions during the non-growing season then rainfed crop production may not be affected by a decrease in annual water yield (unless the changes in the off-season affect water storage and soil productivity in the growing seasons). Second, even if water availability decreases during the growing season farmers can adapt by changing planting patterns or management such that productivity does not decline [115]. (Others have argued, however, because farmer adaptation to climate change may take many years and involve large sunk costs [106], a change in water yield on rainfed cropland will have, at least in the short run, a negative affect on productivity.)

Change in aboveground biomass carbon storage

Let Zj indicate the total mass of aboveground and belowground biomass carbon stored as of 2000 in country j's grid cells that convert to urban or cropland use by 2015 [116]. Let , , and indicate the average Mg ha−1 of biomass carbon stored in j's urban, cropland, and less-intensely managed grid cells as of 2000, respectively, where less-intensely managed grid cells are any non-cropland and non-urban grid cells ([116] and Text S1). The change in biomass carbon in country j from 2000 to 2015, measured in metric tons, due to land conversion only, is given by,(14)

The first term of equation (14) gives the expected biomass carbon storage as of 2015 in cells that convert to urban use in country j (assuming that new urban areas have attained the average storage values of urban areas that existed as of 2000). The second term gives the expected aggregate biomass carbon storage in cells that convert to cropland use in country j (assuming that new urban areas have attained the average storage values of urban areas that existed as of 2000) The last term gives the expected aggregate biomass carbon storage in abandoned cropland grid cells (that do not convert to urban use) less the biomass carbon stored in the land when it was in cropland in 2000 (assuming that abandoned cropland areas have attained the average storage values of less-intensely managed areas that existed as of 2000). Recall that we do assign a particular vegetation cover to abandoned cropland. However, we do not use the specific biomass carbon storage values associated with these covers in equation (14); instead we use a country-wide average storage value associated with all less-intensely managed types. We do this because resulting vegetative cover on abandoned cropland is highly speculative on our part and using the average value across all less-intensely managed types is more conservative.

The metric does not account for 1) carbon accumulation in grid cells that do not experience a LULC change (e.g., the sequestration from 2000 to 2015 in forests that mature over that period); 2) land management activities that may affect sequestration rates on converted land; and 3) the affect of climate change on storage capacities and sequestration rates (ha−1 storage estimates are from circa 2000). See Figure S6 for maps of .

Avoided emissions analysis

The first step in this analysis is to identify which nations would have been eligible to generate avoided emission credits from 2000 to 2015. Avoided emission credits will only be given to developing nations that are predicted to experience deforestation rates greater than historic rates. Let Dj represent the predicted annualized deforestation rate from 2000 to 2015 in country j where,(15)

Fj is the forested area in country j in 2000, and is a scenario's forested area in j in 2015. Let Djb indicate the observed per annum 1990 to 2000 deforestation rate in country j [77]. A developing country would have been eligible to begin generating avoided emissions credits beginning in 2000 if Dj>Djb.

We assume the value of urban land is always larger than any potential value of an offset. Therefore, an eligible country would have only generated avoided emission credits through avoided conversion of forest to cropland. The maximum number of credits that a country can generate from avoiding forest conversion to cropland is equal to the predicted biomass carbon emissions between 2000 and 2015 due to deforestation for cropland that is above and beyond the historic deforestation baseline rate, or,(16)where Ajk are the hectares of forest type k in country j in 2000 that are projected to be in cropland by 2015 under a scenario, Aj = , CO2jk is the average CO2-equivalent (CO2e) of carbon stored in biomass ha−1 of forest type k in j in 2000 ([116], Text S1, and Table S20). The first term in equation (16) gives j's share of emissions due to expected deforestation from 2000 to 2015 in j that are eligible for credits. The second term gives the total forest biomass CO2e in forest area expected to be lost in j from 2000 to 2015 due to cropland conversion. The credit limit avoidj could be higher if the credit limit formula included the emissions from forest expected to be cleared for urban use. We assume that an avoided emission credit would be in force up to 2020. However, because we assume that none of these emissions can be realistically avoided, avoidj is only equal to the cropland sector's share of . See column A in Table S21 for a list of countries where Dj>Djb under each scenario and column B for avoidj values under each scenario.

To determine what portion of avoidj that j would sell we need information on 1) the net price of a biomass CO2e credit for the period 2000 to 2020 and 2) the opportunity cost of keeping forested parcels forested instead of cleared for agriculture. Let pc be the net price of a biomass CO2e credit for the period 2000 to 2020 where c includes all program costs associated with a credit that are incurred by the landowner. In a research environment without data limitations we would determine two unique values for each cell forested as of 2000: 1) the net revenues associated with keeping the grid cell in forest up to 2020, including the net value of the avoided deforestation credit and 2) the net returns associated with clearing the grid cell at some point between 2000 and 2015 for crop production up to the year 2020. Then, assuming each grid cell manager is a net revenue maximizer, we would assign avoided emission credits to each grid cell where avoided deforestation behavior maximized the manager's net revenues (subject to the credit cap).

Due to data limitations, however, we only generate a country-level estimate of net returns to agriculture and therefore cannot make a parcel-by-parcel comparison of net returns to maintaining forest cover versus net returns to clearing and cropland use (although we could have used the cropland suitability layer in an attempt to diffuse average net returns across a country) Instead, we calculate the expected net present value (NPV) of all projected deforestation for cropland use in j according to a scenario by multiplying Aj by Vj, the average per hectare expected NPV of converting forested area in j to cropland use in 2010 for use up to 2020 ([7], [117], [118], Text S1, and column D of Table S21). We assume that Vj is equal to 15% of the present value of agricultural revenues in country j [118]. If,(17)or(18)then the country would, on average, earn more from forestalling all deforestation that produces avoidj until 2020. In other words, we assume that all cropland that emerges on forested land as of 2000 in j under a scenario is avoided if inequality (18) is met. See column G in Table S21 for the right hand side of inequality (18) for each eligible country j under each scenario. We model pc values of $5 and $150 per Mg of CO2e.

Supporting Information

Figure S1.

Biomass carbon content on land converted to urban or cropland use between 2000 and 2015.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.s002

(0.21 MB JPG)

Figure S3.

Areas where significant irrigation use is assumed if the grid cell is in cropland use.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.s004

(0.37 MB JPG)

Figure S4.

Cropland suitability map for the country scenario. Scores have been normalized within a country so cross country comparisons are not appropriate.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.s005

(0.45 MB JPG)

Figure S5.

Cropland suitability map for the regional scenario. Scores have been normalized within a region so cross region comparisons are not appropriate.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.s006

(0.49 MB JPG)

Figure S6.

Net loss of biomass carbon between 2000 and 2015 due to LULC change. Results are summarized at the country-level and presented in Mg ha−1 units.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.s007

(0.36 MB JPG)

Table S1.

Irrigated and rainfed cropland grid cell area in 2000 and 2015 under both scenarios.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.s008

(0.09 MB XLS)

Table S2.

Urban grid cell area in 2000 and 2015 under both scenarios.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.s009

(0.07 MB XLS)

Table S3.

Regions and their member countries in the regional scenario.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.s010

(0.03 MB XLS)

Table S4.

Change in cropland grid cell area under the country scenario.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.s011

(0.07 MB XLS)

Table S5.

Crop grid cell area growth rate for each region under the regional scenario.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.s012

(0.03 MB XLS)

Table S6.

Change in cropland grid cell area under the regional scenario.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.s013

(0.04 MB XLS)

Table S7.

Estimates of equation (10) in Text S1.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.s014

(0.04 MB XLS)

Table S8.

Observed irrigation intensity in grid cells assigned irrigated cereal yield by country.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.s015

(0.06 MB XLS)

Table S9.

The fraction of cropland grid cell area in each cropping zones under both scenarios.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.s016

(0.07 MB XLS)

Table S10.

The average yield of each crop or crop group in 2000 by country (Mg ha−1).

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.s017

(0.07 MB XLS)

Table S11.

Expected growth in yields by crop or crop group and country.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.s018

(0.06 MB XLS)

Table S12.

Calories per crop or crop type.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.s019

(0.05 MB XLS)

Table S13.

The relative difference in cropland suitability in 2015 versus 2000 by country.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.s020

(0.06 MB XLS)

Table S14.

The relative mix of crops or crop groups produced in each country in 2000: q = year 2000 crop mix.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.s021

(0.07 MB XLS)

Table S15.

Alternative 2015 crop mix by country: q = 2 (“Low” 2015 harvested hectare mix).

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.s022

(0.07 MB XLS)

Table S16.

Alternative 2015 crop mix by country: q = 3 (“Mean” 2015 Harvested Hectare Mix).

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.s023

(0.07 MB XLS)

Table S17.

Alternative 2015 crop mix by country: q = 4 (“Mean” 2015 harvested hectare mix).

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.s024

(0.07 MB XLS)

Table S18.

Alternative 2015 crop mix by country: q = projected 2015 crop mix.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.s025

(0.07 MB XLS)

Table S19.

Average water yield on rainfed cropland in 2000 and under both scenarios by country.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.s026

(0.05 MB XLS)

Table S20.

Average biomass carbon storage by forest type by country in 2000 (Mg of carbon equivalent ha−1).

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.s027

(0.05 MB XLS)

Table S21.

Avoided emissions analysis.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0014327.s028

(0.03 MB XLS)

Acknowledgments

The authors wish to thank Taylor Ricketts for providing valuable editorial comments.

Author Contributions

Conceived and designed the experiments: EJN HS PH MC DE SW SM. Performed the experiments: EJN HS PH MC DE SW. Analyzed the data: EJN HS PH MC SP. Wrote the paper: EJN HS MC SP.

References

  1. 1. Millennium Ecosystem Assessment (2005) Ecosystems and human well-being: Synthesis. Washington, DC: Island Press. 155 p.
  2. 2. Tallis HT, Ricketts T, Nelson E, Ennaanay D, Wolny S, et al. (2010) InVEST 1.004 beta User's Guide. Palo Alto: The Natural Capital Project, Stanford. Available: http://invest.ecoinformatics.org/. Accessed 2010 Mar 1.
  3. 3. Lambin EF, Turner BL, Geist HJ, Agbola SB, Angelsen A, et al. (2001) The causes of land-use and land-cover change: Moving beyond the myths. Glob Environ Change-Human Policy Dimens 11: 261–269.
  4. 4. Kareiva P, Watts S, McDonald R, Boucher T (2007) Domesticated nature: Shaping landscapes and ecosystems for human welfare. Science 316: 1866–1869.
  5. 5. Sala OE, Chapin FS, Armesto JJ, Berlow E, Bloomfield J, et al. (2000) Biodiversity - global biodiversity scenarios for the year 2100. Science 287: 1770–1774.
  6. 6. The Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO) (2008) FAOSTAT - production database. Available: http://faostat.fao.org/site/339/default.aspx. Accessed 2008 Aug 14.
  7. 7. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development - The Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (2008) OECD-FAO agricultural outlook 1970-2017. Available: http://www.agri-outlook.org/document/32/0,3343,en_36774715_36775671_40444896_1_1_1_1,00.html. Accessed 2008 Aug 14.
  8. 8. United Nations (2009) United Nations common database. Available: http://unstats.un.org/unsd/cdb_discontinued/cdb_discontinued.asp. Accessed 2008 May 14.
  9. 9. Ramankutty N, Foley JA, Olejniczak NJ (2002) People on the Land: Changes in Global Population and Croplands during the 20th Century. Ambio 31: 251–257.
  10. 10. Verburg PH, Schot PP, Dijst MJ, Veldkamp A (2004) Land use change modelling: Current practice and research priorities. GeoJournal 61: 309–324.
  11. 11. Ebeling J, Yasue M (2008) Generating carbon finance through avoided deforestation and its potential to create climatic, conservation and human development benefits. Proc R Soc Lond [Biol] 363: 1917–1924.
  12. 12. Tacconi L (2009) Compensated successful efforts for avoided deforestation vs compensated reductions. Ecol Econ 68: 2469–2472.
  13. 13. Pirard R, Combes J-L, Combes Motel P (2009) A response to the commentary on “Compensated successful efforts”. Ecol Econ 68: 2179–2181.
  14. 14. Alcamo J, Vuuren Dv, Cramer W, Alder J, Bennett E, et al. (2005) Changes in ecosystem goods and services and their drivers across the scenarios. In: Carpenter S, Pingali P, Bennett E, Zurek M, editors. Ecosystems and Human Well-being: Scenarios, Volume 2. Washington, DC: Island Press. pp. 297–373.
  15. 15. Alcamo J, Vuuren Dv, Ringler C, Alder J, Bennett E, et al. (2005) Methodology for developing the MA scenarios. In: Carpenter S, Pingali P, Bennett E, Zurek M, editors. Ecosystems and Human Well-being: Scenarios, Volume 2. Washington, DC: Island Press. pp. 145–172.
  16. 16. Alcamo J, van Vuuren D, Ringler C, Cramer W, Masui T, et al. (2005) Changes in nature's balance sheet: Model-based estimates of future worldwide ecosystem services. Ecol Soc 10. Available: http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss2/art19/. Accessed 2008 Sep 26.
  17. 17. Rosegrant MW, Cai X, Cline S (2002) World water and food to 2025: Dealing with scarcity. Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute. 322 p.
  18. 18. Alcamo J, Doll P, Henrichs T, Kaspar F, Lehner B, et al. (2003) Global estimates of water withdrawals and availability under current and future “business-as-usual” conditions. Hydrol Sci J -J Sci Hydrol 48: 339–348.
  19. 19. Alcamo J, Doll P, Henrichs T, Kaspar F, Lehner B, et al. (2003) Development and testing of the WaterGAP 2 global model of water use and availability. Hydrol Sci J -J Sci Hydrol 48: 317–337.
  20. 20. Alcamo J, Leemans R, Kreileman E, editors. (1998) Global change scenarios of the 21st century: Results from the IMAGE 2.1 model. Oxford: Pergamon. 308 p.
  21. 21. IMAGE-team (2001) The IMAGE 2.2 implementation of the SRES scenarios: A comprehensive analysis of emissions, climate change and impacts in the 21st century. Bilthoven, The Netherlands: National Institute of Public Health and the Environment.
  22. 22. Carpenter S, Pingali P, Bennett E, Zurek M, editors. (2005) Ecosystems and Human Well-being: Scenarios, Volume 2. Washington, DC: Island Press. 515 p.
  23. 23. Guzy MR, Smith CL, Bolte JP, Hulse DW, Gregory SV (2008) Policy research using agent-based modeling to assess future impacts of urban expansion into farmlands and forests. Ecol Soc 13. Available: http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol13/iss1/art37/. Accessed 2009 May 21.
  24. 24. Hulse D, Branscomb A, Enright C, Bolte J (2009) Anticipating floodplain trajectories: A comparison of two alternative futures approaches. Landscape Ecol 24: 1067–1090.
  25. 25. Nelson GC, Geoghegan J (2002) Deforestation and land use change: Sparse data environments. Agric Econ 27: 201–216.
  26. 26. Nelson E, Polasky S, Lewis DJ, Plantinga AJ, Lonsdorf E, et al. (2008) Efficiency of incentives to jointly increase carbon sequestration and species conservation on a landscape. Proc Natl Acad Sci U S A 105: 9471–9476.
  27. 27. Kamusoko C, Aniya M, Adi B, Manjoro M (2009) Rural sustainability under threat in Zimbabwe – simulation of future land use/cover changes in the Bindura district based on the Markov-cellular automata model. Appl Geogr 29: 435–447.
  28. 28. Landis J, Zhang M (1998) The second generation of the California Urban Futures model. Part 1: Model logic and theory. Environ Plann B 25: 657–666. Part 2: Specification and calibration results of the land-use change submodel. Environ Plann B 25: 795–824.
  29. 29. Clarke KC, Hoppen S (1997) A self-modifying cellular automaton model of historical urbanization in the San Francisco Bay Area. Environ Plann B 24: 247–261.
  30. 30. Manson SM, Geoghegan J, Turner BL II (2006) State of the art in describing future changes in ecosystem services: Forecasting changes in land use and land cover. In: Carpenter S, Pingali P, Bennett E, Zurek M, editors. Ecosystems and Human Well-being: Scenarios, Volume 2. Washington, DC: Island Press. pp. 74–76.
  31. 31. McDonald RI, Kareiva P, Formana RTT (2008) The implications of current and future urbanization for global protected areas and biodiversity conservation. Biol Conserv 141: 1695–1703.
  32. 32. Landis JD (1994) The California Urban Futures model: a new generation of metropolitan simulation models. Environ Plann B 21: 399–420.
  33. 33. Baker JP, Hulse DW, Gregory SV, White D, Van Sickle J, et al. (2004) Alternative futures for the Willamette River Basin, Oregon. Ecol Appl 14: 313–324.
  34. 34. Swetnam RD, Fisher B, Mbilinyi BP, Munishi PKT, Willcock S, et al. (2010) Mapping socio-economic scenarios of land cover change: A GIS method to enable ecosystem service modelling. J Environ Manage. In press.
  35. 35. Goldstein JH, Caldarone G, Colvin C, Duarte TK, Ennaanay D, et al. (2010) Integrating ecosystem services into land-use planning in Hawai'I, TEEB D2 Case Study. Palo Alto: The Natural Capital Project, Stanford.
  36. 36. Johnston RA, Shabazian DR, Gao S (2004) UPlan: a versatile urban growth model for transportation planning. Transport Res Rec 1831: 202–209.
  37. 37. Patz JA, Martens WJM, Focks DA, Jetten TH (1998) Dengue fever epidemic potential as projected by general circulation models of global climate change. Environ Health Perspect 106: 147–153.
  38. 38. Tilman D, Fargione J, Wolff B, D'Antonio C, Dobson A, et al. (2001) Forecasting agriculturally driven global environmental change. Science 292: 281–284.
  39. 39. Arnell NW (2004) Climate change and global water resources: SRES emissions and socio-economic scenarios. Glob Environ Change-Human Policy Dimens 14: 31–52.
  40. 40. Nelson GC, Rosegrant MW, Koo J, Robertson R, Sulser T, et al. (2009) Climate change. Impact on agriculture and costs of adaptation. Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute. 30 p.
  41. 41. Rosegrant MW, Ringler C, Msangi S, Sulser TB, Zhu T, et al. (2008) International Model for Policy Analysis of Agricultural Commodities and Trade (IMPACT): Model Description. Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute. 42 p.
  42. 42. Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency (2006) Integrated modelling of global environmental change. An overview of IMAGE 2.4. Bilthoven, The Netherlands: Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency. 228 p.
  43. 43. DeFries R, Bounoua L (2004) Consequences of land use change for ecosystem services: A future unlike the past. GeoJournal 61: 345–351.
  44. 44. Strengers B, Leemans R, Eickhout B, de Vries B, Bouwman L (2004) The land-use projections and resulting emissions in the IPCC SRES scenarios scenarios as simulated by the IMAGE 2.2 model. GeoJournal 61: 381–393.
  45. 45. Van Minnen JG, Strengers B, Eickhout B (2006) Simulating carbon exchange between the terrestrial biosphere and the atmosphere. In: Bouwman AF, Kram T, Goldewijk KK, editors. Integrated modelling of global environmental change. An overview of IMAGE 2.4. Bilthoven, The Netherlands: Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency. pp. 113–130.
  46. 46. Mueller C, Eickhout B, Zaehle S, Bondeau A, Cramer W, et al. (2007) Effects of changes in CO2, climate, and land use on the carbon balance of the land biosphere during the 21st century. J Geophys Res 112: G02032.
  47. 47. Feddema JJ, Oleson KW, Bonan GB, Mearns LO, Buja LE, et al. (2005) The importance of land-cover change in simulating future climates. Science 310: 1674–1678.
  48. 48. Sala OE, van Vuuren D, Pereira HM, Lodge D, Alder J, et al. (2005) Biodiversity across scenarios. In: Carpenter S, Pingali P, Bennett E, Zurek M, editors. Ecosystems and Human Well-being: Scenarios, Volume 2. Washington, DC: Island Press. pp. 375–408.
  49. 49. Alkemade R, Bakkenes M, Bobbink R, Miles L, Nellemann C, et al. (2006) GLOBIO 3: Framework for the assessment of global terrestrial biodiversity. In: Bouwman AF, Kram T, Goldewijk KK, editors. Integrated modelling of global environmental change. An overview of IMAGE 2.4. Bilthoven, The Netherlands: Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency. pp. 171–186.
  50. 50. Bouwman AF, Van Der Hoek KW, Van Drecht G (2006) Modelling livestock-crop-land use interactions in global agricultural production systems. In: Bouwman AF, Kram T, Goldewijk KK, editors. Integrated modelling of global environmental change. An overview of IMAGE 2.4. Bilthoven, The Netherlands: Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency. pp. 77–92.
  51. 51. Eickhout B, van Meijl H, Tabeau A (2006) Modelling agricultural trade and food production under different trade policies. In: Bouwman AF, Kram T, Goldewijk KK, editors. Integrated modeling of global environmental change. An overview of IMAGE 2.4. Bilthoven, The Netherlands: Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency. pp. 61–76.
  52. 52. Nellemann C, MacDevette M, Manders T, Eickhout B, Svihus B, et al., editors. (2009) The environmental food crisis: Environments role in averting future food crises. Birkeland, Norway: United Nations Environment Programme. 101 p.
  53. 53. Seitzinger SP, Mayorga E, Bouwman L, Kroeze C, Beusen AHW, et al. (2010) Global river nutrient export: A scenario analysis of past and future trends. Global Biogeochem. Cycles. In press.
  54. 54. United Nations Environment Program (2007) Global environment outlook: Environment for development – 4. Valletta, Malta: Progress Press Ltd. 572 p.
  55. 55. Nelson EJ, Daily GC (2010) Modelling ecosystem services in terrestrial systems. F1000 Biology Reports 2: 53.
  56. 56. Tallis HM, Kareiva P (2006) Shaping global environmental decisions using socio-ecological models. Trends Ecol Evol 21: 562–568.
  57. 57. Reid W (2006) Millennium ecosystem assessment survey of initial impacts. Available: http://www.millenniumassessment.org/documents/Document.798.aspx.pdf. Accessed 2008 Jun 17.
  58. 58. Hall CAS, Tian H, Qi Y, Pontius RG, Cornell J (1995) Modelling spatial and temporal patterns of tropical land use change. J Biogeogr 22: 753–757.
  59. 59. Pontius RG, Cornell JD, Hall CAS (2001) Modeling the spatial pattern of land-use change with GEOMOD2: Application and validation for Costa Rica. Agric Ecosyst Environ 85: 191–203.
  60. 60. Center for International Earth Science Information Network-Columbia University, Centro Internacional de Agricultura Tropical (2005) Gridded population of the world version 3 (GPWv3): Population density grids. Available: http://sedac.ciesin.columbia.edu/gpw/global.jsp. Accessed 2008 Sep 12.
  61. 61. Earth Resources Observation and Science Center (EROS) (1996) GTOPO30. Available: http://eros.usgs.gov/#/Find_Data/Products_and_Data_Available/gtopo30_info. Accessed 2008 Oct 23.
  62. 62. United Nations Environment Program-World Conservation Monitoring Centre (2007) World database on protected areas (WDPA) annual release 2007. Available: http://www.wdpa.org/AnnualRelease.aspx. Accessed 2008 Aug 10.
  63. 63. The Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations-The Institute for Applied Systems Analysis (2000) Global agro-ecological zones. Available: http://www.iiasa.ac.at/Research/LUC/GAEZ/index.htm. Accessed 2008 Jul 14.
  64. 64. Lambin EF, Geist HJ (2006) Land-use and land-cover change: local processes and global impacts. Berlin: Springer-Verlag 222:
  65. 65. Rosegrant MW, Paisner MS, Meijer S, Witcover J (2001) Global food projections to 2020. Emerging trends and alternative futures. Washington, DC, : International Food Policy Research Institute.
  66. 66. Solomon S, Qin D, Manning M, Chen Z, Marquis M, et al., editors. (2007) Contribution of working group I to the fourth assessment report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, 2007. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 1056 p.
  67. 67. Budyko MI, Zubenok LI (1961) The determination of evaporation from the land surface. Izv. Ak. Nauk. SSR Se. Geog 6: 6–17.
  68. 68. Budyko MI (1974) Climate and life. San Diego: Academic Press. 508 p.
  69. 69. Milly PCD (1994) Climate, soil water storage, and the average annual water balance. Water Resour Res 3: 2143–2156.
  70. 70. Zhang L, Dawes WR, Walker GR (2001) Response of mean annual evapotranspiration to vegetation changes at catchment scale. Water Resour Res 37: 701–708.
  71. 71. Potter NJ, Zhang L, Milly PCD, McMahon TA, Jakeman AJ (2005) Effects of rainfall seasonality and soil moisture capacity on mean annual water balance for Australian catchments. Water Resour Res 41: W06007.
  72. 72. Donohue RJ, Roderick ML, McVicar TR (2007) On the importance of including vegetation dynamics in Budyko's hydrological model. Hydrol Earth Syst Sc 11: 983–995.
  73. 73. Siebert S, Döll P, Feick S, Hoogeveen J, Frenken K (2007) Global map of irrigated areas version 4.0.1. Available: http://www.fao.org/nr/water/aquastat/irrigationmap/index10.stm. Accessed 2008 Jul 7.
  74. 74. Vera-Diaz MdC, Kaufmann RK, Nepstad DC, Schlesinger P (2008) An interdisciplinary model of soybean yield in the Amazon Basin: The climatic, edaphic, and economic determinants. Ecol Econ 65: 420–431.
  75. 75. Olson DM, Dinerstein E, Wikramanayake ED, Burgess ND, Powell GVN, et al. (2001) Terrestrial ecoregions of the worlds: A new map of life on earth. Bioscience 51: 933–938.
  76. 76. World Wildlife Fund (2006) WildFinder: Online database of species distributions. Available: http://gis.wwfus.org/wildfinder/. Accessed 2008 Aug 13.
  77. 77. The Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (2009) State of the world's forests 2009. Rome: The Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations. 168 p.
  78. 78. United Nations Development Programme (2008) Human development indices. A statistical update 2008. Available: http://hdr.undp.org/en/media/HDI_2008_EN_Content.pdf. Accessed 2008 Aug 13.
  79. 79. Rodriguez JP, Beard TD Jr, Bennett EM, Cumming GS, Cork SJ, et al. (2006) Trade-offs across space, time, and ecosystem services. Ecol Soc 11. Available: http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol11/iss1/art28/. Accessed 2009 May 21.
  80. 80. Byerlee D, de Janvry A, Sadoulet E (2009) Agriculture for development: Toward a new paradigm. Annu Rev Resour Econ 1: 15–35.
  81. 81. Myers SS, Patz JA (2009) Emerging threats to human health from global environmental change. Annu Rev Resour Econ 34: 223–252.
  82. 82. Chatfield C (1953) Food composition tables for international use. Rome: The Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations.
  83. 83. Thurow R, Kilman S (2009) Enough: Why the world's poorest starve in an age of plenty. New York: PublicAffairs. 416 p.
  84. 84. Wikramanayake ED, Dinerstein E, Loucks CJ (2002) Terrestrial ecoregions of the Indo-Pacific: A conservation assessment. Washington, DC: Island Press. 824 p.
  85. 85. IUCN (2001) IUCN red list categories and criteria: Version 3.1. Available: http://www.iucnredlist.org/. Accessed 2008 12 Sep.
  86. 86. Rudel TK, Coomes OT, Moran E, Achard F, Angelsen A, et al. (2005) Forest transitions: Towards a global understanding of land use change. Global Environ Change Part A 15: 23–31.
  87. 87. Nagendra H (2008) Do parks work? Impact of protected areas on land cover clearing. Ambio 37: 330–337.
  88. 88. Plantinga AJ, Richards KR (2008) International forest carbon sequestration in a post-Kyoto agreement. Discussion Paper 2008-11. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Project on International Climate Agreements.
  89. 89. Leff B, Ramankutty N, Foley JA (2004) Geographic distribution of major crops across the world. Global Biogeochem Cycles 18: GB1009.
  90. 90. Steinfeld H, Gerber P, Wassenaar T, Castel V, Rosales M, et al. (2006) Livestock's long shadow - environmental issues and options. Rome: The Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations. 390 p.
  91. 91. Fry JA, Coan MJ, Homer CG, Meyer DK, Wickham JD (2009) Completion of the national land cover database (NLCD) 1992–2001 land cover change retrofit product. Open-File Report 2008–1379. Denver: U.S. Geological Survey. 18 p.
  92. 92. Veldkamp A, Lambin EF (2001) Predicting land-use change. Agric Ecosyst Environ 85: 1–6.
  93. 93. Lambin EF, Geist HJ, Lepers E (2003) Dynamics of land-use and land-cover change in tropical regions. Annu Rev of Env and Resour 28: 205–241.
  94. 94. Keys E, McConnell WJ (2005) Global change and the intensification of agriculture in the tropics. Global Environ Chang 15: 320–337.
  95. 95. You L, Wood S, Wood-Sichra U (2009) Generating plausible crop distribution maps for sub-Saharan Africa using a spatially disaggregated data fusion and optimization approach. Agricult Sys 99: 126–140.
  96. 96. Riebsame WE, Parton WJ, Galvin KA, Burke IC, Bohren L, et al. (1994) Integrated modeling of land-use and cover change. Bioscience 44: 350–356.
  97. 97. Irwin EG, Geoghegan J (2001) Theory, data, methods: Developing spatially explicit economic models of land use change. Agric Ecosyst Environ 85: 7–23.
  98. 98. Lambin EF, Rounsevell MDA, Geist HJ (2000) Are agricultural land-use models able to predict changes in land-use intensity? Agric Ecosyst Environ 82: 321–331.
  99. 99. Naidoo R, Wamura T (2007) Global-scale mapping of economic benefits from agricultural lands: Implications for conservation priorities. Biol Cons 140: 40–49.
  100. 100. Monfreda C, Ramankutty N, Foley , JA (2010) Mapping farming systems of the world: towards a detailed description of global agricultural land use. Submitted to Front Ecol Environ.
  101. 101. Mcdonald RI, Forman RTT, Kareiva P, Neugarten R, Salzer D, et al. (2009) Urban effects, distance, and protected areas in an urbanizing world. Landscape Urban Plann 93: 63–75.
  102. 102. Parton WJ, Stewart JWB, Cole CV (1988) Dynamics of C, N, P and S in grassland soils - a model. Biogeochemistry 5: 109–131.
  103. 103. Bachelet D, Neilson RP, Hickler T, Drapek RJ, Lenihan JM, et al. (2003) Simulating past and future dynamics of natural ecosystems in the United States. Global Biogeochem Cycles 17: 1045.
  104. 104. Santhi C, Srinivasan R, Arnold JG, Williams JR (2006) A modeling approach to evaluate the impacts of water quality management plans implemented in a watershed in Texas. Environ Modell Softw 21: 1141–1157.
  105. 105. Luedeling E, Zhang M, Girvetz EH (2009) Climatic changes lead to declining winter chill for fruit and nut trees in California during 1950–2099. PLoS One 4: e6166.
  106. 106. Schlenker W, Hanemann WM, Fisher AC (2005) Will US agriculture really benefit from global warming? Accounting for irrigation in the hedonic approach. Am Econ Rev 95: 395–406.
  107. 107. Kahn ME (2009) Urban growth and climate change. Ann Rev of Resour Econ 1: 333–349.
  108. 108. Rockstrom J, Steffen W, Noone K, Persson A, Chapin FS, et al. (2009) A safe operating space for humanity. Nature 461: 472–475.
  109. 109. European Commission, Joint Research Centre (2003) Global land cover 2000 database. Available: http://ies.jrc.ec.europa.eu/global-land-cover-2000. Accessed 2008 Jul 7.
  110. 110. Hoekstra JM, Boucher TM, Ricketts TH, Roberts C (2005) Confronting a biome crisis: Global disparities of habitat loss and protection. Ecol Lett 8: 23–29.
  111. 111. Bouwman AF, Fung I, Matthews E, John J (1993) Global analysis of the potential for nitrous oxide (N2O) production in natural soils. Global Biogeochem Cycles 7: 557–597.
  112. 112. Hamon WR (1961) Estimating potential evapotranspiration. J Hydraul Div Proc Am Soc Civil Eng 87: 107–120.
  113. 113. Wolock DM, McCabe GJ (1999) Effects of potential climatic change on annual runoff in the conterminous United States. J Am Water Resour As 35: 1341–1350.
  114. 114. Allen RG, Pereira LS, Raes D, Smith M (1998) Crop evapotranspiration - Guidelines for computing crop water requirements - FAO Irrigation and drainage paper 56. Rome: The Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations.
  115. 115. Mendelsohn R, Nordhaus WD, Shaw D (1994) The Impact of global warming on agriculture: a Ricardian analysis. Amer Econ Rev 84: 753–71.
  116. 116. Ruesch A, Gibbs HK (2008) New IPCC tier-1 global biomass carbon map for the year 2000. Available: http://cdiac.ornl.gov/epubs/ndp/global_carbon/carbon_documentation.html. Accessed 2008 Jul 7.
  117. 117. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development - The Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (2009) OECD-FAO agricultural outlook 1970-2018. Available: http://www.agri-outlook.org/pages/0,2987,en_36774715_36775671_1_1_1_1_1,00.html. Accessed 2008 Jul 7.
  118. 118. Stern N (2007) The Economics of Climate Change. The Stern Review. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 712 p.