Skip to main content
Advertisement
Browse Subject Areas
?

Click through the PLOS taxonomy to find articles in your field.

For more information about PLOS Subject Areas, click here.

  • Loading metrics

Mapping Systemic Risk: Critical Degree and Failures Distribution in Financial Networks

  • Matteo Smerlak ,

    msmerlak@perimeterinstitute.ca

    Affiliation Perimeter Institute for Theoretical Physics, 31 Caroline Street North, N2L 2Y5 Waterloo ON, Canada

  • Brady Stoll,

    Affiliation Department of Mechanical Engineering, University of Texas at Austin, 204 E. Dean Keaton, C2200, Austin, TX 78712, United States of America

  • Agam Gupta,

    Affiliation Indian Institute of Management Calcutta, Diamond Harbour Road, Joka, Kolkata, West Bengal 700104, India

  • James S. Magdanz

    Affiliation Resilience and Adaptation Program, University of Alaska Fairbanks, PO Box 757000, Fairbanks, AK 99775-7000, United States of America

Abstract

The financial crisis illustrated the need for a functional understanding of systemic risk in strongly interconnected financial structures. Dynamic processes on complex networks being intrinsically difficult to model analytically, most recent studies of this problem have relied on numerical simulations. Here we report analytical results in a network model of interbank lending based on directly relevant financial parameters, such as interest rates and leverage ratios. We obtain a closed-form formula for the “critical degree” (the number of creditors per bank below which an individual shock can propagate throughout the network), and relate failures distributions to network topologies, in particular scalefree ones. Our criterion for the onset of contagion turns out to be isomorphic to the condition for cooperation to evolve on graphs and social networks, as recently formulated in evolutionary game theory. This remarkable connection supports recent calls for a methodological rapprochement between finance and ecology.

Introduction

In the financial sector, shock propagation mechanisms are at the core of systemic risk [1, 2], and banks play the most important role [3]. An important and potentially vulnerable arena for financial contagion is the interbank loan market, which allows banks to rapidly exchange large amounts of capital for short durations to accommodate temporary liquidity fluctuations [46]. In a seminal work that laid down a framework for exploring systemic risk, Eisenberg and Noe [7] developed a clearing payment algorithm for the interbank loan market and, subsequently, interbank loan networks have been of particular interest [810].

In recent years, random network theory [11, 12] has provided a useful framework to study contagion effects in interconnected structures [13]. Applied to the financial sector [14], network approaches have clarified the role of connectivity [15, 16], bank size [17], shock size [10] and overlapping portfolios [18] in systemic risks. Increased understanding of contagion in finance [19, 20] has led to an increased interest by regulators and central bankers [21, 22] in using network measures to evaluate systemic risk. Network centrality measures have been widely used by researchers to identify important nodes in financial networks. Battiston et al. [23] introduced DebtRank, a measure based on feedback centrality to identify systemically important nodes. Markose et al. [24] used eigenvector centrality to design a super-spreader tax to make financial systems more robust.

An essential insight of Allen and Gale [25], confirmed in [8] and deepened (with different assumptions) in [16], was that increasing network connectivity—measured by its mean degree z—can have opposite effects depending on the baseline value of z. On the one hand, when the network is sparsely connected, increasing z will open new channels for contagion and weaken the network. On the other hand, when z is sufficiently large, increasing z further will dilute the effect of a localized shock and strengthen the network. From this perspective, the key question is not if, but when, enhanced connectivity helps secure network robustness. Battison et. al. [26, 27], Stiglitz [28], and Roukney [29] incorporated the effects of illiquid assets and potential amplifications of failures due to human behavior in crises. These findings suggested that intermediate-degree networks would be most stable. Additionally, Battiston et. al [26] suggested in case of non-amplification that increasing degree may have an ambiguous relationship with contagion depending on the parameter values of initial robustness. However, these studies assumed a normal distribution of initial robustness. We focus on the initial failures of the system as studied by Allen and Gale—not amplifications—and study more realistic financial networks where initial distribution of robustness may not be normal.

Our first goal in this paper is to sharpen these results by introducing a model of interbank lending that allows the “critical degree” separating these two regimes to be computed as an explicit function of a small number of relevant financial parameters: (interbank and external) interest rates, liquidity requirement, leverage ratio. As we shall see, this critical degree is pivotal in deriving an analytical estimate of the number of failures induced by a single shock given these parameters. Our results complement those of [8], who used the mathematics of percolation theory [30] to determine the contagion threshold in financial networks, as well as those of [9], who brought to bear the “mean-field approximation” familiar to statistical physicists. However, the relationship between the critical degree and the economic environment is hidden in Gai and Kapadia’s work within an unspecified “probability that a bank is vulnerable”. We unpack this connection explicitly.

Our second goal is to analyze the role of degree heterogeneity in financial networks with regard to systemic risk. It has long been known [31, 32] that network topology is a key determinant of network robustness. Empirical studies of flows over the Fedwire Funds Services [33, 34] have found the network to be inhomogeneous, with a strongly connected, strongly reciprocal core and a much more sparse periphery. (Similar analyses have been conducted of interbank loan networks in Belgium [35], Austria [36], the Netherlands [37], Italy [38], and East Asia [39], with similar results.) Nonetheless, most theoretical studies of the systemic risk to date [8, 9, 25] have used homogeneous (Erdös-Rényi) networks. We show that, when banks’ degrees have a fat-tailed distribution, the number of failures induced by a single shock follows a similar distribution—a precise statement of the “robust-yet-fragile” property of financial networks emphasized by several authors [8, 10, 40].

The paper is organized as follows. We begin by describing our model of interbank lending networks, first in some generality and then under simplifying assumptions. Next we show how the number of failures induced by an individual shock can be estimated analytically by means of a mean-field-type approximation, in which Cayley trees (regular networks without loops) play an instrumental role. We then compare our results with numerical simulations of both homogenous and scalefree random networks. We close with a few remarks concerning the policy implications of our work, and point out an intriguing biological analogy.

Results

A network model of interbank lending

We present a model of the structure of interbank lending as a random weighted directed network, in which a node i ∈ {1, ⋯, N} represents a bank and a link ij with weight lij a loan of amount lij made by i to j. The sum of all weights flowing out of a bank i, li = ∑ji lij, is therefore the total interbank exposure of bank i; the sum of weights flowing into i, bi = ∑ji lji, is in turn the total liability of bank i on the interbank market. We call “(first) neighbors” two banks which share a direct link. When a bank j is connected to another bank i through a path of length larger than one, we say that j is a “higher order neighbor” of i.

In addition to its interbank liabilities bi, we assume that each bank i has external, more senior liabilities si (e.g. deposits). We assume that all of these (interbank and senior) liabilities will be available for reinvestment in external investment opportunities at a later time period. On the asset side, we further introduce liquid assets λi (e.g. bonds) as well as illiquid assets ιi (e.g. buildings). The total assets Ai and total liabilities Li of bank i can therefore be written as Ai = li+λi+ιi and Li = bi+si; the difference Ki = AiLi is the net worth of bank i, see Table 1.

Basel III [41] introduced leverage and liquidity requirements for banks. We define for each bank i the leverage ratio Λi = Ki/Ai (ratio of networth to total assets) and the liquidity ratio fi = λi/Ai (ratio of liquid assets to total assets). By definition, lowering the ratios Λi and fi increases the exposure of bank i on the interbank market; we shall see that they have a strong impact on the systemic risk.

We now introduce a discrete-time investment dynamic, through which a bank can either increase or decrease its net worth Ki. We assume that the investment period is shorter than the time needed to liquidate illiquid assets. The period begins with the balance sheet introduced in Table 1. In the first step, a bank uses its initial total liabilities Li to invest in some external opportunity, at some interest rate Ri. (Successful investments correspond to Ri > 1, hazardous ones correspond to Ri < 1; in the worst case scenario, the investment is lost in full, viz. Ri = 0.) We denote ρi = (Ri − 1)Li the profit made in this transaction. (If a bank only borrows and does not lend, bi > 0 and li = 0, we take ρi = (Ri − 1)bi; equivalently, the profit is defined by ρi = (Ri − 1)max{Li, bi}.) In the second step, a bank uses this profit and its liquid assets λi to repay its interbank liabilities li with an interest r > 1 while ensuring the seniority of si. When a bank i can just repay its interbank borrowings, we say that i is critical. (See Methods for details.)

From a mathematical perspective, finding the interbank repayments xi (a.k.a. the clearing vector) amounts to solving the system of N coupled, non-linear equations (1) where [⋅]+ = max{ ⋅, 0} and the sum ranges over i’s debtors; the repayment xij of bank i to bank j is then given by xij = lij xi/bi, as first proposed by Eisenberg and Noe [7]. After all repayments are made, bank i has an updated net worth (2) We call safe the banks i such that , and failed the ones such that .

While the set of Eq (1) can be studied numerically for various network topologies and different values of the financial parameters Ri, fi, Λi and r, our goal in this paper is to obtain explicit, analytical results about the robustness of financial networks with respect to shocks. To make progress, we make the following—dramatic but empowering—assumptions: (i) all loans are reciprocated, so that the network is actually undirected and loans are made in the same amount in both directions, (ii) all interbank loans lij have unit value, so that li = bi = ki, where ki is the degree of node i, (iii) all banks have equal leverage and liquidity ratios (Λ, f), so that the latter can be thought of as model parameters rather than individual variables (iv) illiquid assets are negligible (ιi = 0), and (v) external interest rates Ri take the same value R > 1 for all banks across the network except one (bank i = i0, call it the “shocked bank”), for which Ri0 = 0.

The reciprocity of the “core” of real financial networks is very high [33], making our first assumption less unrealistic than may seem at first sight. Garlaschelli [42] found that real networks are typically highly reciprocal or highly areciprocal, and Musmeci [43] determined that exposure is related to topology. Networks with non-reciprocal links provide an example of an interesting extension of this work. The assumption of unitary loans is made in order to provide a simplistic yet analytical solution. This allows for general lessons to be learned from our analysis, rather than more realistic but less widely applicable solutions. Simplistic assumptions to enhance analytical tractability have often been used in finance literature. For example, Freixas et al [44], Aghion et al. [19], Diamond and Dybvig [45] and Postlewaite and Vives [46] have all made simplifying assumption about unitary deposits to study individual bank insolvency. We additionally analyzed perturbations in this assumption, see Supporting Information for details.

Our third assumption represents a worst case scenario in which all banks within a financial network are operating at the limit of regulatory caps, such as the Basel norms. The fourth assumption is due to the model set up, whereby the two periods we analyze are much shorter than the time in which illiquid assets could be liquidated. The assumption of uniform external interest rates is made based on an assumption that the banks are operating in a similar environment.

Our model then creates a single shock to the system, in the form of one bank losing its external investement. Due to interbank lending, all other banks in the network can in principle feel the effects of this shock, either directly (first neighbors, direct creditors) or indirectly (higher order neighbors, indirect creditors). Within this setting, our objective is to estimate the understand the onset of contagion, in particular through the number of induced failures F (the number of banks ii0 such that ), as a function of the financial parameters (R, r, Λ, f) and of the network topology.

Failures on Cayley trees

We begin our investigation of the model by considering the simplest network topology, namely a network with uniform degree k and no loops (a “Cayley tree”). On such simple networks, the repayment problem (1) can be solved exactly as follows (see Methods and Supporting Information for details).

When k is sufficiently large, each neighbor of the shocked bank i0 inherits only a small fraction of i0’s losses—and none fails. For networks with incrementally decreasing degree k, however, the effect of these losses on the net worth of each creditor of i0 gradually increases, until at some point shocked bank i0’s weakest neighbor also fails. If degree k further decreases, the second (then third, etc.) order neighbors of i0 also approach criticality, and start failing as well.

This sequence of transitions, involving higher and higher order neighbors of the shocked bank, defines an ordered sequence of “critical degrees” such that (3) where N(p)(k) = k(k−1)p−1 is the number of nodes at distance p from i0. The values of these critical degrees provide a measure of the robustness of the network with respect to a shock: the higher the critical degrees, the more fragile the financial structure.

The expression for each as a function of the financial parameters (R, r, f, Λ) can be obtained by solving the repayment Eq (1) under these conditions that (i) all banks at distance dq from the shocked bank are safe, but (ii) all q-th neighbors of i0 are critical. This gives in particular (4) The critical degrees and (given explicitly in Supporting Information) are plotted as functions of the financial ratios (f, Λ) for R = 1.02 and r = 1.01 and as functions of the interest rates (R, r) for f = 50% and Λ = 3% in Fig 1. As is apparent from these plots, are stricly decreasing functions of f and Λ: lower liquidity and leverage ratios both enhance the systemic risk—an intuitive conclusion, which is here proved rigorously. Furthermore, we see that, unlike the first critical degree , the second critical degree never becomes appreciably large, , so that failures in effect hardly extend beyond the first neighbors of the shocked bank. Finally, we note that, in the limit where Λ, f → 0 (a regime in which the economy is dominated by interbank transactions), the first critical degree reaches the value 1/(R − 1); we will come back to this observation in the concluding section.

thumbnail
Fig 1. The first two critical degrees and as functions of the liquidity ratio f and of the leverage ratio Λ for R = 1.05, r = 1.01 (Fig 1a) and as functions of the external rate R and the interbank rate r for f = 50% and Λ = 3% (Fig 1b).

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0130948.g001

Failures on general networks

Real-world financial networks being anything but regular, the usefulness of the exact solution above would seem to be extremely limited. It turns out to be the opposite. In the regime where failures are unlikely to extend beyond the first neighbors of the shocked bank—which is the case for most realistic values of the financial parameters, as illustrated by the low values of in Fig 1—knowing the first critical degree (hereafter denoted simply k*) yields a reliable estimate of the distribution of number of failures P(F) (hereafter “failures distributions”) on random networks, including scalefree ones. We focus our analysis on this regime.

We will assume that, on a general random network, a first neighbor i of the shocked bank will indeed fail if and only if its own degree ki is smaller than the critical degree k* given by Eq (4). This is akin to the “mean-field” approximation familiar from statistical mechanics: it replaces the actual, inhomogeneous, environment of i in the network by a homogeneous environment in which all banks have the same degrees as i, here the Cayley tree with degree ki. While this approximation clearly cannot capture all the dynamics of a single network, it does provide a tractable starting point to study the statistics of failure contagion in a given ensemble of random networks. Within this approximation, we obtain the following results (see Methods and Supporting Information for details).

First, we have an explicit lower bound on the expected number of failures (5) where is the probability that a neighbor of the shocked bank i0 has a subcritical degree. Here p(k) is the degree distribution (probability that a node has degree k) and p(l|k) is the conditional degree distribution (probability that a node attached to a node with degree k has degree l). The positive remainder ⟨F⟩−∑k ≥ 1 kp(k)q(k) corresponds to the contribution of higher order neighbors, which is neglected here. Note that formula (5) implies that disassortative financial networks (for which the probability q(k) that a neighbor of the shocked bank has subcritical degree increases with the number of neighbors k) tend to be more vulnerable to contagion than assortative or uncorrelated ones [32]. (In the latter case, one checks that Eq (5) reduces to , where q(k) = q is independent of k.)

Second, we show that, whether the network is Poisson-distributed (p(k) ∼ zk/k!) or power-law distributed (p(k) ∼ kγ), the failures distributions P(F) has the same asymptotic behavior as the degree distribution itself. This can be understood as follows. This is because, for the number of failures F to be large in the regime where only first neighbors of the shocked bank can fail, one needs: (i) the shocked bank i0 to have large degree k, and (ii) many neighbors of i0 to have subcritical degree lk*. The correlation of k and l being a decreasing function of |kl|, these two conditions become independent in the limit kk* ≥ l, in which case the failures distribution P(F) simply reflects the degree distribution p(k). In the scalefree case, this means in particular that P(F) has a power-law falloff with exponent γ, hence is fat tailed. This result can be interpreted as expressing the “robust-yet-fragile” property of scalefree networks noted earlier: even when the expected number of failures ⟨F⟩ is low, the risk remains that a single shock can take down a significant fraction of the network.

Numerical tests

To test the validity of these findings, we analyzed two additional types of random networks for which the conditional probability distribution p(l|k) is known explicitly as a function of the mean degree z (at least in the large N limit): the classical Erdös-Rényi (ER) model [47], with Poisson degree distribution, and the Barabási-Albert (BA) model [48], with scalefree degree distribution P(k) ∼ k−3, see Fig 2.

thumbnail
Fig 2. Failures in sample networks with N = 53 and z = 4: Cayley tree (Fig 2a), ER network (Fig 2b), BA network (Fig 2c). The black node indicates the shocked bank, the red nodes the failed banks, the green nodes the safe banks.

Here R = 1.02, r = 1.01, f = 50% and Λ = 3%.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0130948.g002

For both network types, we generated 104 random networks for each value of the mean degree z. We solved Eq (1) numerically for each of these networks and, using Eq (2), we computed the number of induced failures F over the whole network. From this we determined the mean number of failures over all of the randomly generated networks and the empirical failures distribution at each z. We compared these distributions with our mean-field bounds. Finally, we checked that using directed networks (both random and scalefree) does not yield significantly different results, thereby confirming the validity of assumption (i) as a useful first approximation.

Fig 3 shows the mean number of failures ⟨F⟩ as a function of the mean degree z for homogeneous ER and scalefree BA networks, in the parameter regime R = 1.02, r = 1.01, f = 50% and Λ = 3% (for which k* ≃ 10.2); see also Figure B in S1 Text. Irrespective of the network topology, we find that the empirical value of ⟨F⟩ matches very closely with our estimate Eq (5) provided that the mean degree is not too small. This discrepancy at low z has a straightforward explanation: while we neglected their contribution in our mean-field approximation, we saw with Cayley trees that the likelihood of second and higher order neighbors failing is a decreasing function of z.

thumbnail
Fig 3. Mean number of failures as a function of mean degree z, as estimated analytically (circles) and as obtained numerically (dots), for ER networks (Fig 3a) and BA networks (Fig 3b).

The dashed line indicates the value of the critical degree k*. The discrepancy between the empirical and theoretical values at low z is due to the contribution of second neighbors, neglected in our approximation.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0130948.g003

Fig 4, in turn, plots the empirical distribution of failures P(F) and our analytical estimate thereof (given in Methods) for ER and BA random networks with z = 8, for the same values of the financial parameters. Here too, we find that the agreement between the numerical results and the prediction of our mean-field approximation is very good; Fig 4b confirms in particular that P(F) is fat-tailed when p(k) is (for BA networks).

thumbnail
Fig 4. Statistics of failures in ER networks (Fig 4a) and BA networks (Fig 4b), for R = 1.02, r = 1.01, f = 50% and Λ = 3%.

Observe the “robust-yet-fragile” nature of scalefree networks: while the maximum expected number of failures is lower than for ER networks, the probability of catastrophic failures is much higher.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0130948.g004

The close agreement for these values of the financial parameters (and any other values such that k* ≲ 15, see Supporting Information) is remarkable if one contrasts the complexity of the original problem (1) with the extreme simplicity of our mean-field approximation. To us, this conclusion is the main import of our study: once the expression for the critical degree k* as a function of the financial parameters has been obtained, Eq (4), analytical results on the systemic risk are not only possible, but also intuitive and straightforward.

Discussion

We have considered the effect of financial variables such as interest rates, leverage ratio and financial exposure on the robustness of interbank systems vis-à-vis individual shocks. Focusing first on regular networks, we obtained an explicit formula for the critical degree, below which failures begin to propagate through the network. From this, we then showed how to derive a simple but reliable lower bound on the expected number of failures and failures distribution in random (and possibly strongly heterogeneous) networks. Besides an in-depth study of cascades beyond first neighbors of the shocked bank, interesting extensions of our work could include a non-linear relation between interbank exposure and network degree, overlapping portfolios, multiple or probabilistic shocks, multiple-period dynamics, and amplifications of failures. Additionally, our assumptions, particularly reciprocal loans, could be relaxed to more realistically represent real-world networks.

The highly stylized character of our model notwithstanding, our results shed new light on important aspects of systemic risks, such as the association between contagion and interest rate policy [44]. Using plausible values for interest rates, liquidity requirement and leverage, we found critical degrees k* of the order of 5 to 10. An empirical analysis of the FedFunds market [33] found a mean degree z ≃ 15, but almost half of the banks had out-degrees less than 4, thus vulnerable to contagion. As mentioned previously, is nearly always < 5, and therefore can significantly impact contagion. In the 2008 financial crisis, mean degrees in the interbank network declined, increasing systemic risk [49]. While regulators do not directly control the topology of financial networks, it is useful to understand how tools already in place—interest rates, leverage and liquidity requirements—can affect the critical degree.

We observed that our formula (4) for the critical degree k* reduces to 1/(R − 1) in the high leverage, low liquidity limit. This limiting value can be expressed as a “cost-benefit” rule of thumb, as follows. If bank i lends l to bank j and j does not repay i, i will have lost l; if on the other hand j makes a successful investment with the money borrowed from i and repays it in full, j will have made a profit profit (R − 1)l. The critical degree k* is then just the ratio of the potential loss l to the potential profit (R − 1)l of each transaction. Given the great difficulty of the problem of assessing the robustness of actual financial networks, this simple rule of thumb could prove a handy “order-zero” approximation.

What is more, this interpretation establishes a direct link with a seemingly unrelated problem: the condition for the evolution of cooperation, famously investigated by Hamilton [50]. Ref. [51] recently extended his insights to graphs and social networks, showing that “natural selection favours cooperation, if the benefit of the altruistic act, b, divided by the cost, c, exceeds the average number of neighbours, k, which means b/c > k”. This simple rule is precisely the same as the one we found for shock propagation in high-leverage, low liquidity interbank networks: the critical degree is given by the ratio of the activities promoting systemic propagation (benefit of cooperation and interbank lending respectively) to the activities inhibiting systemic propagation (cost of cooperation and external profits respectively). This unexpected connection supports the convergence of ecology and finance advocated by Haldane and May after the 2008 crisis [52], and points to a unified perspective on resource sharing in networks.

Methods

Repayment equations

Denoting xij the amount repaid by bank i to bank j in the second step, we assume the following repayment rules.

  • Full repayment: if ρi+λisi+∑ji xjirbi, bank i repays its junior debt rbi in full, hence for each ji
  • Partial default: if 0 < ρi+λisi+∑ji xji < rbi, bank i repays a fraction of its junior liabilities on a pro rata basis, hence for each ji
  • Complete default: if ρi+λisi+∑ji xji ≤ 0, bank i repays nothing, hence xij = 0 for each ji.

We call critical a bank i such that (6)

Networks

In this paper we considered three classes of networks: Cayley trees, ER networks and BA networks. They are defined as follows.

  • Cayley trees are graphs without loops in which each node is connected to a fixed number of neighbors k. Given an (arbitrarily chosen) “root” node i0, the number of nodes at distance d from i0 is k(k − 1)d−1.
  • ER networks are the simplest random networks: given N nodes, each possible edge is included in the network with probability ϕ, independently from every other edge. When N ≫ 1, this results in a random network with Poisson degree distribution (7) where z = ϕ(N − 1) is the mean degree. The absence of correlations in such networks entails that the conditional degree distribution—the probability that a node connected to a node with degree k has degree l—is just p(l|k) = lp(l)/z.
  • BA networks are obtained by means of a stochastic growth process. Starting from a complete graph over (say) m initial nodes, each new node is added to m existing nodes with a probability that is proportional to the number of links that the existing nodes already have. In the large time limit, this process defines a correlated random network with (conditional) degree distribution [53] (8) (9) where km; the mean degree is given by z = 2m.

Distribution of first-neighbors failures

Here we estimate the probability P1(F1) that F1 first neighbors of the shocked bank fail. Clearly, the probability that F banks fail throughout the network (in addition to the shocked bank i0 itself) is larger than the probability that F first neighbors of i0 fail, i.e. P(F) ≥ P1(F). In the main text we made the approximation P(F) ≃ P1(F) and confirmed its validity numerically.

Consider a random network with degree distribution p(k) and conditional degree distribution p(k|l). Suppose that the shocked bank i0 has degree k, and let be the probability that a neighbor of the shocked bank i0 has a subcritical degree. According to our “mean-field” assumption, the probability that F1 neighbors of i0 fail is given by the probability that F1 neighbors have subcritical degree, times the probability that kF1 first neighbors have supercritical degree, times the number of choices of F1 failing neighbors among k. Weighing this by the probability p(k) that i0 has k neighbors, we arrive at (10) The expected number of first-neighbor failures is then obtained by evaluating ⟨F1⟩ = ∑F1 ≥ 1 F1 P(F1) (see Supporting Information). Note that expression (10) is strongly reminiscent of the classical theory of percolation on complex networks, where one shows [54] that the degree distributions p′(k′) after the removal of a fraction q of the nodes is given in terms of the old degree distribution p(k) by . This is no surprise: the whole point of our mean-field approximation is to reduce a dynamical problem (computation of repayments) to a topological one (failure depends on degree only).

Large degree asymptotics

Let us now consider the limit of Eq (10) when F1 ≫ 1 (hence for shocked banks with degree k ≫ 1), assuming that q(k) becomes independent of k in this limit. (This amounts to saying that correlations between the degrees k and l of adjacent nodes become immaterial when |kl| ≫ 1; this holds for both ER and BA networks.) Let us consider Poisson-distributed and power-law distributed networks separately (see Supporting Information for details).

  • Poisson networks. Given the Poisson degree distribution p(k) = ez zk/k!, resumming Eq (10) is straighforward and gives (11)
    Thus, in Poisson distribued networks, the failures distribution is Poissonian with mean zq.
  • Scalefree networks. For scalefree networks we observe that, when γ is an integer and for sufficiently large k, the Pochhammer symbol (k)γ = k(k+1)…(k+γ − 1) can be substituted to kγ in the degree distribution p(k) ∼ 1/kγ. This allows to perform the sum (10) explicitly, yielding (12) where 2𝓕1 is the Gauss hypergeometric function, whose asymptotics for large parameters is given in [55]. Analytical continuation in γ then shows that P1(F1) is scalefree with exponent γ also for non-integer γ.

In both cases, the tail of P1(F1) has the same nature (Poisson or power-law) as the degree distribution itself.

Supporting Information

S1 Text. Computation of critical degrees, mathematical proofs and further numerical results, including the effect of loan asymmetry (Figure A) and varying interest rates and leverage ratios (Figure B).

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0130948.s001

(PDF)

Acknowledgments

We thank the participants and staff of the 2013 Santa Fe Institute Complex Systems Summer School (where this project was initiated) for a very stimulating experience. We are especially indebted to T. J. Carter, R. Martinez and M. M. King and for their help in the early stages of this research, and to B. Vaitla for drawing our attention to Ref. [51]. Useful discussions with V. Bonzom are gratefully acknowledged. Research at the Perimeter Institute is supported in part by the Government of Canada through Industry Canada and by the Province of Ontario through the Ministry of Research and Innovation.

Author Contributions

Analyzed the data: MS BS. Contributed reagents/materials/analysis tools: MS BS. Wrote the paper: MS BS AG JSM. Reviewed the literature: AG JSM. Wrote the Supplementary Information: MS.

References

  1. 1. De Bandt, O. & Hartmann, P. Systemic risk: A survey. ECB Working Paper 35 (2000).0
  2. 2. Allen F., Babus A. & Carletti E. Financial Crises: Theory and Evidence. Annu. Rev. Fin. Econ. 1, 97–116 (2009).
  3. 3. Billio M., Getmansky M., Lo A.W. & Pelizzon L. Econometric measures of connectedness and systemic risk in the finance and insurance sectors. J. Finan. Econ. 104, 535–559 (2012).
  4. 4. Furfine C. H. The Microstructure of the Federal Funds Market. Financ. Mark. Inst. Instrum. 8, 24–44 (1999).
  5. 5. Ashcraft A.B. & Duffie D. Systemic illiquidity in the federal funds market. Am. Econ. Rev. 97, 221–225 (2007).
  6. 6. Taylor, J. B. & Williams, J. C. A Black Swan in the Money Market. NBER Working Paper 13943, 36 (2008).
  7. 7. Eisenberg L. & Noe T. H. Systemic risk in financial systems. Management Sci. 47, 236–249 (2001).
  8. 8. Gai P. & Kapadia S. Contagion in financial networks. Proc. R. Soc. A 466, 2401–2423 (2010).
  9. 9. May R.M. & Arinaminpathy N. Systemic risk: the dynamics of model banking systems. J. Roy. Soc. Interface 7, 823–838 (2010).
  10. 10. Acemoglu, D., Ozdaglar, A. & Tahbaz-Salehi, A. Systemic risk and stability in financial networks. Columbia Business School Research Paper No. 13–4 (2013).
  11. 11. Newman M. Networks: An Introduction (Oxford University Press, 2010).
  12. 12. Barrat A., Barthelemy M. & Vespignani A. Dynamical processes on complex networks (Cambridge University Press, 2008).
  13. 13. Watts D. J. A simple model of global cascades on random networks. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 99, 5766–5771 (2002). pmid:16578874
  14. 14. May R.M., Levin S.A. & Sugihara G. Complex systems: Ecology for bankers. Nature (London) 451, 893–895 (2008).
  15. 15. Nier E., Yang J., Yorulmazer T. & Alentorn A. Network models and financial stability. J. Econ. Dyn. Control 31, 2033–2060 (2007).
  16. 16. Battiston S., Delli Gatti D., Gallegati M., Greenwald B. & Stiglitz J. E. Liaisons dangereuses: Increasing connectivity, risk sharing, and systemic risk. J. Econ. Dyn. Control 36, 1121–1141 (2012).
  17. 17. Arinaminpathy N., Kapadia S. & May R. M. Size and complexity in model financial systems. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 109, 18338–18343 (2012). pmid:23091020
  18. 18. Caccioli, F., Shrestha, M., Moore, C. & Farmer, J. D. Stability analysis of financial contagion due to overlapping portfolios. SFI working paper 2012-10-018 (2012).
  19. 19. Aghion P., Bolton P. & Dewatripont M. Contagious bank failures in a free banking system. Eur. Econ. Rev. 44, 713–718 (2000).
  20. 20. Furfine C. H. Interbank Exposures: Quantifying the Risk of Contagion. J. Mon. Cred. Bank. 35, 111–128 (2003).
  21. 21. Kambhu J., Weidman S. & Krishnan N. New directions for understanding systemic risk: a report on a conference cosponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of New York and the National Academy of Sciences (National Academies Press, 2007).
  22. 22. Bisias D., Flood M.D., Lo A.W. & Valavanis S. A Survey of Systemic Risk Analytics. U.S. Department of Treasury, Office of Financial Research 0001 (2012).
  23. 23. Battiston S., Puliga M., Kaushik R. & Tasca P., Caldarelli G., DebtRank: Too Central to Fail? Financial Networks, the FED and Systemic Risk. Nature Sci. Rep. 2, 541 (2012).
  24. 24. Markose S.,Giansante S & Shaghaghi A.R. ‘Too interconnected to fail’ financial network of US CDS market: Topological fragility and systemic risk J Econ Behav Organ 83, 627–646 (2012).
  25. 25. Allen F. & Gale D. Financial Contagion. J. Polit. Econ. 108, 1–33 (2000).
  26. 26. Battiston S., Gatti D.D., Gallegati M., Greenwald B. & Stiglitz J. Default cascades: When does risk diversification increase stability?. J. Financ. Stab. 8, 138–149 (2012).
  27. 27. Battiston S., Gatti D.D., Gallegati M., Greenwald B. & Stiglitz J. Liaisons dangereuses: Increasing connectivity, risk sharing, and systemic risk. J. Econ. Dyn. Controle 36, 1121–1141 (2012).
  28. 28. Stiglitz J. E. Risk and Global Economic Architecture: Why Full Financial Integration May Be Undesirable. Am. Econ. Rev. 100, 388–392 (2010).
  29. 29. Roukny T., Bersini H., Pirotte H., Caldarelli G. & Battiston S. Default Cascades in Complex Networks: Topology and Systemic Risk. Scientific Reports 3, 2759 (2013). pmid:24067913
  30. 30. Newman M.E., Strogatz S.H. & Watts D. J. Random graphs with arbitrary degree distributions and their applications. Phys. Rev. E 64, 026118 (2001).
  31. 31. Albert R., Jeong H. & Barabási A.-L. Error and attack tolerance of complex networks. Nature (London) 406, 378–382 (2000).
  32. 32. Newman M. Assortative Mixing in Networks. Phys. Rev. Lett. 89, 208701 (2002). pmid:12443515
  33. 33. Soramäki K. & Bech M.L., Arnold J., Glass R.J. & Beyeler W. E. The topology of interbank payment flows. Physica A 379, 317–333 (2007).
  34. 34. Bech M.L. & Atalay E. The topology of the federal funds market. Physica A 389, 5223–5246 (2010).
  35. 35. Degryse H. & Nguyen G. Interbank exposures: An empirical examination of contagion risk in the Belgian banking system. Int. J. Cent. Bank. 3, 123–171 (2007).
  36. 36. Boss M., Elsinger H., Summer M. & Thurner S. Network topology of the interbank market. Quant. Financ. 4, 677–684 (2004).
  37. 37. Pröpper M., van Lelyveld I. & Heijmans R. Towards a Network Description of Interbank Payment Flows 177, 1–27 (2008).
  38. 38. Mistrulli P.E. Assessing financial contagion in the interbank market: Maximum entropy versus observed interbank lending patterns. J. Bank. Financ. 35, 1114–1127 (2007).
  39. 39. Inoguchi M. Interbank market, stock market, and bank performance in East Asia. Pac.-Basin Fin. J. 25, 136–156 (2013).
  40. 40. Haldane A. Why banks failed the stress test. BIS Review 18 (2009).
  41. 41. Basel C. Basel III: A global regulatory framework for more resilient banks and banking systems. Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2010).
  42. 42. Garlaschelli D., Loffredo M.I., Patterns of Link Reciprocity in Directed Networks. Phys. Rev. Lett 93, 268701–1 (2004). pmid:15698035
  43. 43. Musmeci N. & Battiston S., Caldarelli G., Puliga M. & Gabrielli A. Bootstrapping Topological Properties and Systemic Risk of Complex Networks Using the Fitness Model. J. Stat. Phys. 151, 720–734 (2013).
  44. 44. Freixas X., Martin A. & Skeie D. Bank liquidity, interbank markets, and monetary policy. FRB of New York Staff Report 371 (2010).
  45. 45. Diamond D. & Dybvig P. Bank runs, deposit insurance, and liquidity. The journal of political economy, 401–419 (1983).
  46. 46. Postlewaite A. & Vives X. Bank runs as an equilibrium phenomenon. The journal of political economy, 485–491 (1987).
  47. 47. Erdős P. & Rényi A. On random graphs. Publ. Math.-Debrecen 6, 290–297 (1959).
  48. 48. Barabási A.-L. & Albert R. Emergence of scaling in random networks. Science 286, 509–512 (1999). pmid:10521342
  49. 49. Minoiu C. & Reyes J.A. A network analysis of global banking: 1978–2010. J. Financ. Stab. 9, 168–184 (2013).
  50. 50. Hamilton W. D. The genetical evolution of social behaviour. I. J. Theor. Biol. 7, 1–16 (1964). pmid:5875341
  51. 51. Ohtsuki H., Hauert C., Lieberman E. & Nowak M. A. A simple rule for the evolution of cooperation on graphs and social networks. Nature (London) 441, 502–505 (2006).
  52. 52. Haldane A.G. & May R. M. Systemic risk in banking ecosystems. Nature (London) 469, 351–355 (2011).
  53. 53. Fotouhi B. & Rabbat M. Degree correlation in scale-free graphs. Eur. Phys. J. B 86, 1–19–19 (2013).
  54. 54. Cohen R., Erez K., ben Avraham D. & Havlin S. Breakdown of the Internet under Intentional Attack. Phys. Rev. Lett. 86, 3682–3685 (2001). pmid:11328053
  55. 55. Temme N. M. Large parameter cases of the Gauss hypergeometric function. J. Comput. Applied. Math. 153, 441–462 (2003).