Skip to main content
Advertisement
Browse Subject Areas
?

Click through the PLOS taxonomy to find articles in your field.

For more information about PLOS Subject Areas, click here.

  • Loading metrics

A model for foreign exchange markets based on glassy Brownian systems

  • M. A. Sánchez-Granero ,

    Roles Conceptualization, Data curation, Formal analysis, Investigation, Methodology, Software, Validation, Visualization, Writing – original draft, Writing – review & editing

    misanche@ual.es

    Affiliation Department of Mathematics, University of Almería, Almería, Spain

  • J. E. Trinidad-Segovia,

    Roles Conceptualization, Formal analysis, Investigation, Methodology, Project administration, Supervision, Writing – original draft, Writing – review & editing

    Affiliation Department of Economics and Business, University of Almería, Almería, Spain

  • J. Clara-Rahola,

    Roles Conceptualization, Data curation, Formal analysis, Investigation, Methodology, Resources, Supervision, Validation, Writing – original draft, Writing – review & editing

    Affiliations Department of Applied Physics, University of Almería, Almería, Spain, i2TiC Multidisciplinary Research Group, Open University of Catalonia, Barcelona, Spain

  • A. M. Puertas,

    Roles Conceptualization, Formal analysis, Investigation, Methodology, Software, Validation, Visualization, Writing – original draft, Writing – review & editing

    Affiliation Department of Applied Physics, University of Almería, Almería, Spain

  • F. J. De las Nieves

    Roles Conceptualization, Formal analysis, Investigation, Methodology, Project administration, Supervision, Writing – original draft, Writing – review & editing

    Affiliation Department of Applied Physics, University of Almería, Almería, Spain

Abstract

In this work we extend a well-known model from arrested physical systems, and employ it in order to efficiently depict different currency pairs of foreign exchange market price fluctuation distributions. We consider the exchange rate price in the time range between 2010 and 2016 at yearly time intervals and resolved at one minute frequency. We then fit the experimental datasets with this model, and find significant qualitative symmetry between price fluctuation distributions from the currency market, and the ones belonging to colloidal particles position in arrested states. The main contribution of this paper is a well-known physical model that does not necessarily assume the independent and identically distributed (i.i.d.) restrictive condition.

Introduction

Since Fama [1] showed that the normal distribution does not fit the empirical distribution of stock market returns, which is leptokurtic and has heavy tails, financial market distributions have become a topic in financial literature. According to McDonald [2], the normal and the log-normal distributions were widely used mainly for two reasons: the estimation of their parameters becomes relatively simple and provides appropriate descriptive models in most cases. Today it is not easy to summarize research papers proposing different distributions in financial markets around the world. A distribution widely used in the literature has been the Student one. This distribution seems to be helpful for two reasons: first, it is adequate in resolving distribution tails and second, when the number of degrees of freedom is greater than 30, the Student distribution converges to a normal one.

Alternatively, Mandelbrot [3] proposed to replace the Brownian motion approach resulting from the normal distribution, by a model based on a symmetric stable Levy motion of parameter α < 2. After Mandelbrot’s paper, the Levy distribution family became very popular as they account for asymmetry and heavy tails. For example, Press [4] introduced an exponential Levy process model with a non-stable distribution based in a superposition of Brownian motion and an independent compound Poisson process with normally distributed jumps. Madan and Seneta [5] proposed a Levy process with gamma variance distributed increments and Barndorff [6] used the family of generalized hyperbolic distributions. Later, Eberlein and Keller [7] introduced an exponential hyperbolic Levy motion, Koponen [8] employed the geometric stable laws, Kozubowski and Panorska [9] considered the multivariate geometric stable distribution or Kozubowski and Podgorski [10] proposed the asymmetric Laplace one, which is a subclass of geometric stable distributions. Note that such distributions allow for asymmetry, they have finite moments of any order, their densities have explicit forms and the estimation of their parameters is easy.

As final remark about the use of the stable family in finance, it must be mentioned that Kim et al. [11] developed the modified tempered stable and Koponen [12], Boyarchenko and Levendorskii [13], Carr et al. [14] introduced the classical tempered stable distribution.

The use of stable families in finance has been conditioned mainly due to the difficulty to estimate the parameters which are well-known only in limiting cases. Another problem associated with this family of distributions is the overestimation of tail indices when samples are not large enough, the infinite second moment and that they do not account for the peakedness around the origin often seen in stock returns.

A different contribution was presented by Login [15] who proposed a Frechet distribution to model extreme returns. Clark [16] and Epps and Epps [17] introduced in foreign exchange markets the so-called mixture distribution hypothesis (MDH) by assuming the strong correlation between trading volume and volatility of exchange rates. In this line, Tauchen and Pitts [18] derived the joint distribution of daily price changes and transactions volumes from a model of intraday equilibrium price changes and intraday volumes. Recent contributions are due to Masoliver et al [19], where a stochastic model for high frequency data in the Standard and Poor’s 500 cash index is presented, Masoliver and Montero [20] where the authors introduce a continuous time random walk model to model the US dollar/Deutsche Mark future and finally Masoliver and Perello [21] where an Exponential Ornstein-Uhlenbeck stochastic volatility model is proposed, which is able to capture multi-scale behavior in the volatility autocorrelation.

Most of the models developed so far propose different distributions considering stylized facts in financial data. The advance in computation methods have allowed researchers to use more complex distributions with more flexible parameters, thus better descriptions of empirical data have been achieved. However, a major problem still remains: estimations are not stable enough in time and the independent and identically distributed (iid) hypothesis persists. In fact, a single functional form is often not able to depict the whole distribution spectrum [22, 23]. In view of such scenario, it is often the case that a pieced functional form is considered in order to quantitatively model financial distributions, where usually a Gaussian distribution is taken when focusing on the central peak of the distribution, while Levy flights are the ones employed in describing heavy distribution tails [24].

In our approach, we present a model which is characteristic to the dynamics of many different physical particle systems, such as atomic glasses, undercooled fluids, granular matter, polymer and colloidal gels, … [25]. All of these systems have in common that their global dynamics is very slow, or even arrested; density fluctuations take very long time to relax, showing viscoelastic behaviour. Microscopically, this is rationalized considering that particles are caged by their own neighbors.

Recall that in fluids at high temperature or gasses, fluctuations in the density can relax very fast because molecules are highly movable, whereas in solids, the motion of single molecules is strongly hindered, disabling the relaxation of local stresses. In undercooled fluids, an intermediate situation is found. At short times, the rattling of the particles inside the cage results in short time dynamics, which saturates when the cage is explored, while long time diffusion requires cooperativity of the neighbors to allow the escape of the particle. This is also interpreted physically by using a free energy hyper-surface, which, in supercooled fluids or glasses, has multiple shallow minima: the vibrations within a single minimum correspond to the rattling in the cage, and long time dynamics is described as jumps from one minimum to another one.

Different models have been developed to describe the dynamics of these systems, and in particular hopping models have been reported. However, please observe that the existing literature concerns models where important restrictions, such as restricted number of investors, restricted market volume or restricted positions, must be considered [26]. Also, other models do not provide a fundamental scope [27], such as the one proposed in this work. Here price fluctuations from the currency exchange market are depicted through a physical model proven valid for a wide variety of physical systems, for example atomic and molecular ones. Namely, we have focused on a particular model proposed by Chaudri et al. [25], where two time scales are considered for the jump from minimum to minimum, and it has been extended to the study of currency exchange rates. We have found that such model is an excellent description to financial distributions, such is the case to the Euro—US dolar [28], among other currencies presented in this work. Noteworthly, this analysis does not assume the data to be independent and identically distributed, i.i.d. Furthermore, the parameters that are employed in the model keep physical significance and therefore, not only a single functional form describing the full distribution range has been found, but even more, the physical understanding that underlies the model allows us to rationalize financial markets.

Here it is important to remark that our approach is as well useful from an applied point of view as it allows developing analysis and instruments aimed at market operations. Furthermore, it must be pointed out that the already mentioned combination of Gaussian and Levy distributions are often used by hedge funds and investors in general in order to monitor market activity and develop investing strategies. Within this regard, the model presented in this manuscript can be very effective because a single description is proposed, where for example, the probability of price changes and its range can be statistically determined. However, we would like to emphasize that our main contribution is the extrapolation of a well known model used for supercooled or arrested states in glassy physics to study the behaviour of foreign exchange rate markets.

This paper is structured as follows: section 2 introduces some of the most important findings of financial literature of foreign exchange rate markets; section 3 describes our physical model; section 4 shows the results of the fits in different currencies and finally section 5 contains the main conclusions.

Foreign exchange markets: A market characterization

In this section we summarize from Sarno and Taylor [29] some characteristics of the microstructure of the foreign exchange market which are relevant to our model.

The foreign exchange market presents some special characteristics over other financial markets. It is a decentralized market in which not all dealer quotes are observable, since trades need not be disclosed and transaction does not occur with just one institution, so different prices can be transacted at the same time. This implies that order flow is not a reliable source of data. Additionally, market makers are responsible for most of the trading volume and this role is assumed mainly by commercial and investment banks. On the other hand, foreign exchange markets are the clearest example of continuous market because it is open 24 hours a day except weekends, and trading volume is the most extensive around the world. This feature explains why the foreign exchange market is among the most efficient ones.

The role assumed by investment banks is for several authors [3032] the reason why market evolution is largely unexplained by movements from macroeconomic fundamentals. Many works in the field also do not assume that only public information is relevant to exchange rates [33].

Financial literature also shows (see [3335]) that time aggregated order flow variables could be more powerful than macroeconomic variables in explaining the exchange rate behavior.

A standard assumption in foreign exchange markets has been that expectations are rational, but the literature provides evidence of risk premia and rejects the rational expectation hypothesis. It seems clear by most of the authors that the formation process used by agents in the foreign exchange market is likely to be more complex than other markets, and that heterogeneity of expectations is crucial [36]. We would like to remark the work of Frankel and Froot [37] which presents a formal model of agent expectations in the foreign exchange market, where agents are classified as chartists, fundamentalists and portfolio managers. They conclude that the value of a currency can then be driven by the decisions of portfolio managers who consider a weighted average of the expectations of fundamentalists and chartists. Here we find another crucial point in exchange rate literature, namely, the role of analysts.

The discrepancy between short and long run exchange rate expectations could be attributable to market participants that use chartist analysis for short run whereas the technique used for long run is fundamental analysis or conventional portfolio models. Evidences are given by Allen and Taylor [38], Taylor [36], Menkhoff [39, 40] and Cheung and Wong [41, 42], Cheung and Chinn [43]. All authors conclude that economic fundamentals will win in the long term and that short term price movements may be dominated by chartist analysis.

Introducing the model

In Clara et al. [28], a model borrowed from physical glasses, that has proven successful when describing data from experiments and simulations [25], is introduced to describe the fluctuations of the euro—US dollar (EURUSD) currency pair. Here, we test such model with many different currency pairs: Pound sterling—Japanese yen (GBPJPY), Australian dollar—Canadian dollar (AUDCAD), New Zealand dollar—Singapur dollar (NZDSGD), US dollar—Mexican peso (USDMXN), Euro—Swiss franc (EURCHF), Pound sterling—Polish zloty (GBPPLN), US dollar—Chinese yuan (USDCNH), US dollar—Hong Kong dollar (USDHKD) and US dollar—Turkish lira (USDTRY). We aim to resolve if the model can be applied to the currency market in general and not only to the EURUSD case. Therefore, we have selected different currency pairs in order to test such approach. We use data with a frequency of 1 minute for periods of one year, from 2010 to 2016 (depending on data availability).

We focus on price fluctuations in the currency pair, and study the distribution of the logarithmic return (in short, log-return) for a given lag time τ, r(τ) = log(p(t0 + τ)/p(t0)). (Alternatively, the log-return can be also defined as r(τ) = log(p(t0)/p(t0τ))). Probability distribution functions (pdfs) from currency rates exhibit a symmetric profile with long tails, specially for small values of τ. These pdfs are common to all the currencies under study and the overall profile is about the same. Note that in [28] the bare price fluctuation is used, but in this work we study the log-return instead, thus, we can compare among different pairs.

Typically, the study of financial log-return distribution (see the introduction) is modelled by using a distribution that provides a good description of experimental data, but without any other significant meaning. Other authors make strong assumptions about the number and the kind of agents. The model we use is based on a model introduced to study particle displacements in physical glasses, where every particle is ideally caged by its own neighbors, restricting the structural relaxation of the whole system. Thermal fluctuations, however, allow particles to jump from one cage to another, on a large time scale.

The model proposed here is based on the description of the free energy landscape of supercooled liquids as a hypersurface composed by many shallow minima, where the system is transiently trapped before a jump is attempted to a different minimum (in contrast, in fluids, the landscape is almost flat, whereas in crystalline solids, it has a deep absolute minimum, corresponding the crystal structure) [44]. The extrapolation to financial markets proposed here assumes that a given currency pair moves in a free energy with many shallow minima, as shown schematically in Fig 1. Two different processes can be immediately identified: i) vibrations within a single minimum, and ii) jumps to other minima. Even more, because the system is expected to be trapped longer in deeper minima, it can be assumed that the first jump out of this deep minimum has a longer waiting time, whereas subsequent jumps will occur faster, as the system is exploring other minima. Our model takes into account all of these processes.

thumbnail
Fig 1. Schematic representation of the energy landscape.

Schematic representation of the energy landscape as a function of the price.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0188814.g001

The vibrations inside a local minimum is described by an Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process, given by (1) with r the logarithm of the return, as defined previously, D the diffusion coefficient and α = D/l2, with l the size of the cage [4547]. This process depicted originally a particle describing Brownian motion with a linear central force pulling it towards its origin, and has been adapted to a one-dimensional motion.

Long range jumps are possible on a larger time scale, according to a Gaussian distribution: (2) where d is the typical size of the jumps. As mentioned previously, different waiting times are considered for the first and all other subsequent jumps. Both probabilities are drawn from an exponential distribution. For the first jump, has a typical time τ1, while subsequent jumps occur faster according to , with a time scale τ2 < τ1.

The overall log-return distribution, G(r, t) depicts the probability of a log-return r, at time span t, and it is calculated in the Fourier-Laplace domain, G(q, s). G(r, t) is recovered by back transforming to the log-return–time domain as:

(3)

Here , is the Fourier transform of function f(r), q is the conjugate variable of log-return r in the Fourier space and FT−1 denotes the Inverse Fourier Transform.

In physical glasses, this model allows the identification of systems with fast or slow dynamics—high or low temperature fluid, respectively [25]. In a high temperature fluid, the relaxation of local fluctuations is fast because the molecules or particles are highly mobile, whereas in a supercooled fluid this relaxation is much slower. In the model, the former is identified by τ1τ2 and ld, whereas for low temperature fluids, τ1τ2 and dl. Within the picture of the energy landscape, the former indicates that there are no independent basins, and movement of the system through this hypersurface is rather smooth and continuous. On the other hand, τ1τ2 and dl signal the presence of independent minima, with a highly restricted motion. For very long lag times (ττ1), the theoretical pdf indeed crosses over to a Gaussian distribution, because the price has experienced many jumps with time scale τ2, and the contribution from the initial jump can be neglected. This is indeed observed in the experimental pdf [28].

To estimate the parameters of the model, we use the absolute moments as follows: we try to optimize an objective function f(params) = ∑oO fm(o), where O is a set with the selected order of the moment, in our case O = {0.1,1,2,3,4} and fm(o) is the difference in the absolute moment of order o between the empirical data and the theoretical distribution corresponding to the given parameters and for a wide range of lag times: fm(o) = ∑tT|log(mome(t))−log(momt(t))|/o, where mome(t) = < |ri(t)|o>, momt(t) = E(|r(t)|o), with ri(t) the empirical log-return with lag t and r(t) the theoretical log-return with lag t for the given parameters, and T is a selection of time lags, in our case {[ez]: z = 0, 0.5, 1.0, 1.5…,7}.

Since moments of low (high) order give weight to the maximum (tails) of the distribution, our selection of moments for the fitting is aimed to obtain a good fitting in all regions of the pdf, including the mean (o = 1) and variance (o = 2). Note that we use the absolute moment of order 0.1 to improve the fit around the mode, since the empirical distribution is quite peaked. On the other hand, for some pairs we found few extreme values of the distribution that we do not consider when fitting the parameters, since these values affect too much the absolute moment while are not so representative of the overall distribution. Additionally, by fitting these moments, we ensure to capture the most relevant features of the experimental pdf, such as its skewness (given by the third moment), or the kurtosis (fourth moment).

The final goodness of the fitting is tested by the maximum difference between the experimental and theoretical cumulative distribution function (CDF), calculated as (4) where and , with r the log-return, are the CDF. Because the pdf is normalized, g(x) grows monotonically from 0 to 1. In most cases, the maximum difference is below 0.05, showing the good quality of the fitting; particular cases are discussed below.

A typical fitting is analyzed in Fig 2 by presenting the absolute moments of order 0.1, 1, 2, 3, 4 of the AUDCAD currency pair for the year 2010 (taken as an example), as well as the absolute moment of the fitted model. The fitting is very good for all moments, in particular for the moment of order 0.1. This guarantees that the distribution calculated from the model reproduces the experimental one, as shown below (see Fig 3).

thumbnail
Fig 2. Absolute moments.

Absolute moments of order 0.1, 1, 2, 3, 4 (from top to bottom) of AUDCAD for the year 2010.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0188814.g002

thumbnail
Fig 3. Pdf of AUDCAD.

Pdf of AUDCAD with lag times 10, 30, 100 and 250 minutes, for the year 2010. The lines are the pdfs obtained from the moment fittings shown in Fig 2.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0188814.g003

Results

The fitted probability density functions for lag times of 10, 30, 100 and 250 minutes are shown for the AUDCAD currency pair in Fig 3. As expected from the comparison of the moments, the experimental distributions can be fitted by our model with good quality. In particular, the different trends of the pdf for short and large log-returns are correctly captured for all lag times. The maximum distance between the experimental and theoretical CDF is in this case below 2% in all cases, confirming the validity of the model to reproduce the experimental pdf. Recall that the same set of parameters {D, l, d, τ1, andτ2} is used for all the pdfs shown in the figure, demonstrating the capability of the model presented here.

The fitting parameters are given in Table 1 (top row), with the parameters for all other fittings discussed below. Note that τ1 and τ2 are very similar, which, within the model, indicates that the dynamics is very fast, similar to a fluid at high temperature (in any case, recall that τ1τ2, as imposed by the model). The parameters l and d indicate the size of the cage and length of jumps, as previously explained. For 2010, the model interprets the AUDCAD exchange rate as vibrating in the range ca. 0.14% and jumps out of this “cage”, within a time scale of two hours approximately, to a value 0.115% apart. The similarity of l and d confirms that the dynamics of this system is fast, i.e. there are no independent minima in the energy landscape (in systems with slower dynamics, it is expected that the separation between the minima is larger than the average size of the basins, ld).

thumbnail
Table 1. Fitting parameters of the model for different currency pairs and years.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0188814.t001

Fittings of similar accuracy are obtained for all other years of this pair, as illustrated in Fig 4, corresponding to the pdf of the year 2014. The parameters for all years considered here are indicated in the Table 1 (first block). Note that the time scales from all years, τ1τ2, which, as discussed previously, indicates that AUDCAD currency pair displays fast dynamics, similar to a fluid at high temperature. The time scale, however, varies from the initial magnitude of two hours within a range of one hour in these years. The length scales, for the cage and jumps, evolve also in this period but stay within the range of [0.05%,0.15%]. For all these years and lag times, the maximum separation between the experimental and theoretical CDF is below Er = 0.04. Note that to the AUDCAD currency pair and as well to all other currencies presented in this work (see Tables 1 and 2), τ1 and τ2 are of about one to three hours. Such hallmark can be qualitatively understood. Short term investors and traders operate in a time range of few hours, and thus determine the short-time dynamics of currency markets. Also, they act synchronized with other financial markets and floors (as operations are not restricted to one market), in particular the NYSE, even by following their schedules related to low (night) and high (morning) activity. Therefore, these agents place operations according to a daily schedule, at particular moments, which impacts market dynamics and the location of stronger or weaker price fluctuations in time, thus setting the magnitude of τ1 and τ2.

thumbnail
Table 2. Fitting parameters of the model for different currency pairs and years.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0188814.t002

thumbnail
Fig 4. Pdf of AUDCAD.

Pdf of AUDCAD with lag times 10, 30, 100 and 250 minutes, for the year 2014.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0188814.g004

Such currency pair, the AUDCAD one, is particularly interesting, as according to the European Central Bank report [48], since the beginning of the financial crisis in 2007, the involvement of non-traditional foreign currencies in international reserves has been tripled. This tendency has been lead by the Canadian dollar (CAD) and Australian dollar (AUD), which represents approximately 25 percent of the non-traditional world reserves. This tendency is consequence of, in one hand, the increase of risk perception in traditional currencies and in the other one, the vigour of the economy from both countries.

Let us focus next on the EURUSD pair, exemplified in Fig 5 showing the pdfs for the year 2015. The fittings of the model are also very satisfactory to all years, capturing again the tails at large variations of the exchange (either positive or negative). The parameters for these fittings are presented in Table 1, second block. Different from the previous case, the time scales for the EURUSD exchange rates show a clear trend, with τ1 > τ2 for the period 2010–2013, while τ1 = τ2 for 2014–2016, and concomitantly d ≳ l. This indicates that the dynamics of the EURUSD is more hindered in the former period than in the latter, coincident with the debt crisis in the Eurozone. Interestingly, the maximum distance between the experimental and theoretical CDF is found for the year 2014, where it goes up to Er = 5.5%—for all other years, the difference is below Er = 3%.

thumbnail
Fig 5. Pdf of EURUSD.

Pdf of EURUSD with lag times 10, 30, 100 and 250 minutes, for the year 2015.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0188814.g005

We now study other currency pairs, as introduced above. Fig 6 shows the GBPJPY rates during 2011. A particularly interesting feature is the large time scales for this year 2011 (Fig 6), τ1 = τ2 ≈ 1000 minutes, as the pdf is narrower in this year, although other parameters do not show any specific behavior. The maximum difference is again below Er = 4% for all years and lag times. The pdfs belonging to the change pair of the New Zeland and Singapur dollars (NZDSGD) are studied in Fig 7 for 2014. The fittings are also quite satisfactory (the maximum distance below Er = 4% for all years and lag times) and the parameters, indicated in Table 1, are again consistent with τ1τ2. This pair is also considered not conventional and it is formed by the currencies of two countries that belong to the P4 free trade agreement signed in 2005 and that is avoiding 90% of duties gradually.

thumbnail
Fig 6. Pdf of GBPJPY.

Pdf of GBPJPY with lag times 10, 30, 100 and 250 minutes, for the year 2011.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0188814.g006

thumbnail
Fig 7. Pdf of NZDSGD.

Pdf of NZDSGD with lag times 10, 30, 100 and 250 minutes, for the year 2014.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0188814.g007

The US dollar—Mexican peso (USDMXN) currency pair is studied as indicated in Fig 8 for the year 2015. The model describes the experimental data with excellent agreement (the maximum distance between experimental and theoretical CDF is below Er = 5%), as shown previously for other pairs, with parameters detailed in Table 2, first block. Again, τ1τ2, due to the intense commercial relation between Mexico and the US.

thumbnail
Fig 8. Pdf of USDMXN.

Pdf of USDMXN with lags 10, 30, 100 and 250 minutes for the year 2015.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0188814.g008

Finally, we study the exchange rate between the US dollar and the Hong Kong dollar, depicted in Fig 9 for the year 2016. This particular year is chosen as an example of an imperfect overall fitting, according to our criterion: Er = 8.3%, 5.7%, 5% and 10.6% for lag times τ = 10, 30, 100 and 250 min., respectively. Still, the fitting is quite satisfactory, and the main features of the distribution are captured. The parameters, given as well in Table 2, yield again τ1τ2. Interestingly, the pdfs are narrower in this case than in the previous ones. This is captured in our model by the smallness of parameters l and d, but in all cases d is much larger than l, indicating that the exchange pair is bracketed in a narrow range, and in a time scale τ1τ2 it jumps out to a different value. Other currency pairs have been studied, with the corresponding parameters presented in Table 2.

thumbnail
Fig 9. Pdf of USDHKD.

Pdf of USDHKD with lags 10, 30, 100 and 250 minutes for the year 2016.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0188814.g009

Tables 1 and 2 compile the fitting parameters for all studied currency pairs. Whereas the values of l and d are non-dimensional parameters, because the log-return is used, the time scales are all measured in the same units, allowing a straightforward comparison between different pairs. Note that both τ1 and τ2 are typically in the range of one to three hours, for all pairs. Given the very different currencies studied, this indicates a common origin for the dynamics of the foreign exchange market, irrespective of the particular pair studied. One can think of market makers and short time traders producing the caging process, since they go in and out in their positions, while larger time investors provide transactions on only one side (up or down) of the market. In this context, our analysis indicates that long time investors enter in the market with a time scale of a few hours.

Looking at particular currency pairs, some of them are more stable than other ones. It is interesting to remark the results obtained for the AUDCAD exchange rate, which clearly is the most stable among the years. As mentioned above, this is probably due to both currencies being considered commodity currencies. Other pairs, such as the NZDSGD or the USDHKD, present particular years with different behavior.

As the proposed model successfully resolves the experimental pdfs from currency pairs, we study next the experimental data to notice that there is some autocorrelation in the signal, i.e. r(τ) is not the same as τ × r(1), see Fig 10. This implies that independently identically distributed pdfs with heavy tails cannot be used to model the log-return distribution of a currency pair. In Fig 10, we can see that the empirical distribution of log-returns with lag times of 10 and 30 minutes is not the same as the distribution of an iid process, featured by log-returns with a lag time of one minute. This is in agreement with Hsieh [49], who concluded that observations for the exchange rate of the US dollar were not independently drawn from a heavy tail distribution that remains fixed over time, but from distributions whose parameters change over time. In particular, in this case, the mean and variance change over time and an ARCH model is able to capture most of the nonlinear stochastic dependencies of the data. Following Hsieh’s finding, other works [5052] obtained similar results. GARCH formulations by [5355] went in the same line. With our model, however, we can account for some kind of autocorrelation without the use of additional models.

thumbnail
Fig 10. Comparison of the experimental pdf vs iid one.

Comparison of the experimental pdf (circle) vs iid one (triangles) for EURUSD in the year 2010 for a lag time of 10 minutes (left panel) and 30 minutes (right panel). The solid line is a Gaussian fit to the iid process.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0188814.g010

It can also be noticed in Fig 10 that the empirical distributions are more peaked than the iid process, and that these have heavier tails. This is in agreement with our model, since the Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process, which cages the price, produces a more peaked distribution, while the jump component explains the larger tails. In terms of the market, we can think of market makers and short time traders producing the caged process, since they keep in and out trading positions, while larger time investors provide transactions on only one side (up or down) of the market, accounting for the jump component.

Indeed, as we pointed out in previous sections, foreign exchange markets present some characteristics that make them different from other financial markets, of which the more important ones are that major trading volume is given by market makers, as well as decentralization. Market makers play a fundamental role in prices formation, and considering that these market operators have the obligation of trading at published prices, over which a margin has been fixed, it seems logical to think that they necessarily contribute to engage market price. On the other hand, as [37] showed, it is proved that short term operators and long term ones trade over the base of different expectations. In foreign exchange markets, long term operators, global banks as well as multinational companies, basically make coverture operations for their commercial transactions. Short term traders, on the other hand, play a similar role to market makers since they use stop loss and profit mechanisms based on chartist analysis. Summarizing, as well as [3335] showed, we think that depending whence the large market trade is coming, from short term or long term traders, the price formation is engaged or not.

Conclusions

We have proposed a model, derived initially to describe the dynamics of undercooled physical systems, that is able to describe currency pairs with a single functional form, and a single set of parameters for all time lags. More importantly, the parameters can can be physically interpreted, making the model more useful. In particular, the ratio of the two time scales involved in the model, τ1 and τ2, indicates if the dynamics of the model corresponds to a high temperature fluid (fast long-time dynamics), or an undercooled system (slow long-time dynamics). We have shown that the model correctly fits many different currency pairs with τ1τ2, for most cases; the time scales for jumps are in the range of one to four hours, pointing to a common origin in all cases. In agreement with Hsieh [49, 53, 54], Milhoj [52], Diebold [50], Diebold and Nerlove [51], McCurdy and Morgan [56] and Kugler and Lenz [55], our model does not assume the iid restricted condition.

The arrested dynamics found by the model, as well as jumps, could be explained by the previous mentioned heterogeneity of expectations pointed out by classic foreign exchange markets literature (see [32, 3638, 5761]). It is suggested that such heterogeneity of expectations is the consequence of the different analysis techniques used by market participants. Traders use information in a different way than portfolio managers and fundamentalists and, in foreign exchange market, one cannot neglect currency coverture operations carried out by international companies. The model presented here does not break the market efficiency hypothesis, but clearly shows how market dynamics transits from arrested, in short term, to diffusive in long term, and we propose, as Engle et al. [62] pointed out, that such behavior is attributed to flow of market information and how market agents process it.

It is interesting to see how not conventional currencies such as AUDCAD and NZDSGD present fits with very stable parameters among the years. In both cases we consider that this is because trade of these currencies is more associated to investments than to speculation.

Acknowledgments

This work has been supported financially by the UOC, under project N11-6139473, aimed at enhancing submission to H2020 calls, (J. C.-R.), the Spanish Ministerio de Economía, Industria y Competitividad and the European Regional Development Fund (ERDF) under projects No. DER2016-76053-R, FIS2015-69022-P and MTM2015-64373-P. The currency exchange data was provided by histdata.com and oanda.com, which we acknowledge.

References

  1. 1. Fama EF. The Behavior of Stock-Market Prices. Journal of Business 1965; 38:34–105.
  2. 2. McDonald JB. Probability distributions for financial models. In: Maddala G.S., Rao C.R., editors. Handbook of statistics, Financial statistics. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Publishers BV, 1996, pp. 427–461.
  3. 3. Mandelbrot BB. The Variation of Certain Speculative Prices. Journal of Business 1963; 36: 394–419.
  4. 4. Press SJ. A compound events model for security prices. Jornal of Business. 1967; 40 (3):317–335.
  5. 5. Madan DB, Seneta E. Chebyshev polynomial approximations and characteristic function estimation. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. Series B 1987;49(2):163–169.
  6. 6. Barndorff-Nielsen OE. Normal inverse Gaussian distributions and stochastic volatility modelling. Scandinavian Journal of Statistics 1997; 24 (1):1–13.
  7. 7. Eberlein E, Keller U. Hyperbolic distributions in finance. Bernoulli 1995;1 (3): 281–299.
  8. 8. Kozubowski TJ. Geometric stable laws: estimation and applications. Mathematical Computational Modelling 1999; 29 (10):241–253.
  9. 9. Kozubowski TJ, Panorska AK. Multivariate geometric stable distributions in financial applications. Mathematical Computational Modelling 1999; 29 (10):83–92.
  10. 10. Kozubowski TJ, Podgórski K. Asymmetric Laplace laws and modelling financial data. Mathematical Computational Modelling 2001; 34 (9–11):1003–1021.
  11. 11. Kim YS, Rachev ST, Bianchi ML, Fabozzi F. Financial market models with Levy processes and time varying volatility Journal of Banking and Finance 2008; 32 (7):1363–1378.
  12. 12. Koponen I. Analytic approach to the problem of convergence of truncated Levy flights towards the Gaussian stochastic process. Physical Review E 1995; 52 (1):1197–1199.
  13. 13. Boyarchenko SI, Levendorskii SZ. Option pricing for truncated Levy processes. International Journal Theoretical and Applied Finance 2000; 3 (3):549–552.
  14. 14. Carr P, German H, Madan D, Yor M. The fine structure of asset returns: an empirical investigation. Journal of Business 2002; 75 (2):305–332.
  15. 15. Longin FM. The Asymptotic Distribution of Extreme market return. The journal of business 1969; 69 (3):383–408.
  16. 16. Clark PK. A Subordinated Stochastic Process Model with Finite Variance for Speculative Prices. Econometrica 1973; 41 (1):135–156.
  17. 17. Epps TW, Epps ML. The Stochastic Dependence of Security Price Changes and Transaction Volumes: Implications for the Mixture of Distributions Hypothesis. Econometrica 1976; 44 (2):305–321.
  18. 18. Tauchen GE and Pitts M. The Price Variability-Volume Relationship on Speculative Markets. Econometrica 1983; 51 (2):485–505.
  19. 19. Masoliver J, Montero M, Porra J. A dynamical model describing stock market price distributions. Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications 2000; 283 (3–4):559–567.
  20. 20. Masoliver J, Montero M, Weis GH. Continuous-time random-walk model for financial distributions. Physical Review E 2003;67 (2):1112.
  21. 21. Masoliver J, Perelló J. Multiple time scales and the exponential Ornstein-Uhlenbeck stochastic volatility model. Quantitative Finance 2005; 6 (5):423–433.
  22. 22. Bouchaud JP, Potters M. Theory of Financial Risks. Cambridge University Press, 2000.
  23. 23. Mandelbrot B, Hudson R. The Misbehavior of Markets. Basic Books, 2006.
  24. 24. Mantegna RN, Stanley HE. Introduction to econophysics: correlations and complexity in finance. Cambridge University Press, 2007.
  25. 25. Chaudhuri P, Berthier L, Kob W. Universal nature of particle displacements close to glass and jamming transitions. Physical Review Letters 2007; 99(6): 060604. pmid:17930812
  26. 26. Cont R, Bouchaud JP. Herd behavior and aggregate fluctuations in Financial Markets. Macroeconomic Dynamics 2000; 4 (2):170–196.
  27. 27. Cont R, Tankov P. Financial modelling with jump processes. Chapman & Hall/CRC Financial Mathematics Series, 2004.
  28. 28. Clara-Rahola J, Puertas AM, Sánchez-Granero MA, Trinidad Segovia JE, de las Nieves FJ. Diffusive and arrestedlike dynamics in currency exchange markets. Physical Review Letters 2017; 118: 068301. pmid:28234526
  29. 29. Sarno L, Taylor MP. The microstructure of foreign exchange markets: a selective survey of the literature. Princeton Studies in International Economics, No. 89; 2001.
  30. 30. Flood RP, Taylor MP. Exchange Rate Economics: What’s Wrong with the Conventional Macro Approach? In: Frankel , Galli , and Giovannini , eds., The Microstructure of Foreign Exchange Markets, 1996, pp. 261–301.
  31. 31. Frankel JA, Rose AK. Chapter 33 Empirical research on nominal exchange rates. In: Handbook of International Economics, 3, 1995, pp. 1689–1729.
  32. 32. Taylor MP. The Economics of Exchange Rates. Journal of Economic Literature 1995; 83 (1):13–47.
  33. 33. Lyons RK. The Microstructure approach to Exchange Rate. Cambridge, Mass. MIT Press; 2001.
  34. 34. Martin D, Evans D, Lyons RK. Order Flow and Exchange Rate Dynamics. Journal of Political Economy 2002; 110 (1):170–180.
  35. 35. Martin D, Evans D, Lyons RK. How is macro news transmitted to exchange rates? Journal of Financial Economics 2008; 88 (1):26–50.
  36. 36. Taylor MP, Allen H. The Use of Technical Analysis in the Foreign Exchange Market. Journal of International Money and Finance 1992; 11 (3):304–314.
  37. 37. Frankel JA, Froot KA. Using Survey Data to Test Standard Propositions Regarding Exchange Rate Expectations. American Economic Review 1987; 77 (1):133–153.
  38. 38. Allen H, Taylor MP. Charts, Noise and Fundamentals in the London Foreign Exchange Market. Economic Journal 1990; 100 (400):49–59.
  39. 39. Menkhoff L. Examining the Use of Technical Currency Analysis. International Journal of Finance and Economics 1997; 2 (4):307–318.
  40. 40. Menkhoff L. The Noise Trading Approach-Questionnaire Evidence from Foreign Exchange. Journal of International Money and Finance 1998; 17 (3):547–564.
  41. 41. Cheung YW, Wong CY. Foreign Exchange Traders in Hong Kong, Tokyo and Singapore: A Survey Study. Advances in Pacific Basin Financial Markets 1999; 5 (1):111–134.
  42. 42. Cheung YW, Wong CY. A Survey of Market Practitioners: Views on Exchange Rate Dynamics. Journal of International Economics 2000; 51 (2):401–419.
  43. 43. Cheung YW, Chinn MD. Macroeconomic Implications of the Beliefs and Behavior of Foreign Exchange Traders. No. w7417. National Bureau of Economic Research; 1999.
  44. 44. Goldstein M. Viscous liquids and the glass transition: a potential energy barrier picture. The Journal of Chemical Physics 1969; 51(9):3728–3739.
  45. 45. Uhlenbeck GE, Ornstein LS. On the theory of the Brownian motion. Physical review 1930; 36(5):823.
  46. 46. Gillespie DT. Exact numerical simulation of the Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process and its integral. Physical review E 1996; 54(2):2084.
  47. 47. Risken H. The Fokker Planck Equation: Method of Solution and Applications. Springer Berlin Heidelberg; 1989.
  48. 48. European Central Bank. The International Role of the Euro. Report of the European Central Bank; July 2013.
  49. 49. Hsieh D.A. The Statistical Properties of Daily Foreign Exchange Rates: 1974–1983. Journal of International Economics 1988; 24 (1–2):129–145.
  50. 50. Diebold FX. Serial Correlation and the Combination of Forecasts. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 1988; 6 (1):105–111.
  51. 51. Diebold FX, Nerlove M. The Dynamics of Exchange Rate Volatility: A Multivariate Latent Factor ARCH Model. Journal of Applied Econometrics 1989; 4 (1):1–21.
  52. 52. Milhoj A. A Conditional Variance Model for Daily Deviations of an Exchange Rate. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 1987; 5 (1):99–103.
  53. 53. Hsieh DA. Modeling Heteroscedasticity in Daily Foreign-Exchange Rates. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 1989; 7 (3):307–317.
  54. 54. Hsieh DA. Testing for Nonlinear Dependence in Daily Foreign Exchange Rates. Journal of Business 1989; 62 (3):339–368.
  55. 55. Kugler P, Lenz C. Are Exchange Rate Fluctuations Random or Chaotic? Schweizerische Zeitschrift für Volkswirtschaft und Statistik 1990; 126 (2):113–128.
  56. 56. McCurdy TH, Morgan LG. Testing the Martingale Hypothesis in Deutsche Mark Futures with Models Specifying the Form of Heteroscedasticity. Journal of Applied Econometrics 1988; 3 (3):187–202.
  57. 57. Frankel JA, Froot KA. Understanding the U.S. Dollar in the Eighties: The Expectations of Chartists and Fundamentalists. Economic Record 1986; 62 (1):24–38.
  58. 58. Frankel JA, Froot KA. Chartists, Fundamentalists, and Trading in the Foreign Exchange Market. American Economic Review 1990; 80 (2):181–185.
  59. 59. Frankel JA, Froot KA. Chartists, Fundamentalists and the Demand for Dollars. In Courakis Anthony and Taylor Mark P., eds. Private Behaviour and Government Policy in Interdependent Economies. Oxford, Clarendon, 1990, pp. 73–126.
  60. 60. Ito T. Foreign Exchange Rate Expectations: Micro Survey Data. American Economic Review 1990; 80 (3):434–449.
  61. 61. Takagi S. Exchange Rate Expectations: A Survey of Survey Studies. International Monetary Fund Staff Papers 1991; 38 (1):156–183.
  62. 62. Engle RF, Ito T, Lin WL. Meteor Showers or Heat Waves? Heteroskedastic Intra-Daily Volatility in the Foreign Exchange Market. Econometrica 1990; 58 (3):525–542.